Optimal Investment Strategy for Defined Contribution Pension Scheme under the Heston Volatility Model ()
1. Introduction
The defined contribution (DC) model is a pension model that has predetermined contribution from the Pension Plan Participant (PPP) and the benefit to the PPP depends on the return on investment of the pension assets. The DC plan is fully funded, privately managed, and there is a third party management of the funds and assets. In this paper, the optimal investment strategies derived with Constant Relative Risk Aversion (CRRA) utility function was considered, volatility was assumed to follow the Heston model with constant interest rate, while salary is stochastic. The PPP in the DC pension plan seeks to maximize certain utility function based on his attitude to risk. The most commonly used utility functions are constant relative risk aversion (CRRA), that is, the power or logarithmic utility function, constant absolute risk aversion (CARA), that is, the exponential utility function and hyperbolic absolute risk aversion (HARA) which is a combo utility function since under different assumptions it can transform to the other types. In this work, the CRRA utility function was used.
2. Theoretical Background
It is a well known fact that the conditional variance of asset returns, especially stock market returns, is not constant over time [1] [2] . Stock return volatility is serially correlated, and shocks to volatility are negatively correlated with unexpected stock returns. Changes in volatility are persistent [3] [4] . Large negative stock returns tend to be associated with increases in volatility that persist over long periods of time. Stock return volatility appears to be correlated across markets over the world [5] .
The groundbreaking papers by Merton [6] opened the floodgates of research on continuous-time portfolio optimization with a constant investment scenario, others have looked at different stochastic scenarios such as stochastic interest rates or stochastic volatility. The investment-consumption problems with the Heston model was considered by [7] .
In [8] and [9] optimal control of a defined contribution pension plan where the guarantee depends on the level of interest rates at the fixed retirement date were considered. [10] measured the effect of a minimum interest rate guarantee constraint through the wealth equivalent in case of no constraints and show numerically the guarantees may induce a significant utility loss for relative risk tolerant investors. [11] the most widely used utility function exhibits constant relative risk aversion (CRRA), that is, the power or logarithmic utility function [12] [13] [14] and [15] .
3. The Model
It is assumed that a PPP who is seeking to maximize the expected utility of his terminal wealth invests in a market made up of risk-free assets and a risky assets. The risky asset is volatile with which can indeed represent the index of the stock market. The dynamics of the underlying assets is given by
(1)
for the riskless asset and
(2)
for the risky asset Where r is a constant risk free interest rate,
is the expected growth rate of the risky asset,
is the volatility of stock with respect to the market forces.
The salary process
is assumed to be constant over the entire working career of the PPP. Let
be the contribution rate of the PPP at time t, then the contribution process
satisfy
(3)
Let
be the wealth process of a PPP at time t. We assume that the fund administrator invests the contribution in η riskless assets and π risky assets, then we have the dynamics of the wealth process as
(4)
substituting (1), (2), and (3) in (4) we have
(5)
simplifying, we have
dividing through by X we have
(6)
where (L(t, V))/X = θ and π/X = Π. in addition V(t) satisfies the Heston model
(7)
where:
is the long variance at
,
k is the rate at which
reverts to
,
Is the volatility of volatility and determines the variance of
.
If
then,
is strictly positive and is said to satisfy the Feller condition.
and
are correlated with correlation coefficient ρ.
4. The Optimal Control and Value Function
4.1. The Admissible Portfolio Strategy
The investor will choose the optimal investment and optimal contribution rate that will maximize the expected utility of terminal wealth of the operation. For an arbitrary admissible strategy
. The objective function G(.) follows:
For admissible portfolio strategy in stocks
: we have
For admissible contribution rate strategy
, we have
Definition. A strategy
which is progressively measurable with respect to
is referred to as an admissible strategy.
Let the collection of all admissible strategies be denoted by A. It then follows that the set A can be defined as follows:
(8)
4.2. The Value Function
Let the value function be defined as
(9)
is the value at time T of a trading strategy that finances
.
is the risk aversion coefficients.
is the subjective discount rate.
determines the relative importance of the intermediate consumption when
, expected utility only depends on the terminal wealth.
The problem confronting the PPP at time t is to select the portfolio weights and contribution rate processes
that maximize the expected utility of terminal wealth of the investor subject to:
We now consider an investor that chooses power utility function. By applying stochastic dynamic programming approach and Ito Lemma our Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation characterized by the optimal solutions to the problem of the investor becomes [5]
(10)
With boundary condition
H is conjectured to have a solution of the form
where
and
are the partial derivatives with respect to t, X and V.
With the above assumptions and the fact that contribution cannot be negative, then the optimal values of the portfolio weight and contributions are:
(11)
and
(12)
Substituting the derivatives as well as the optimal values in (10) resultsin the HJB Equation (7)
(13)
with boundary conditions
5. Solving the PDE
The HJB PDE so derived has no closed form solution, this is mainly as a result of the presence the non homogeneous terms
and
in (13).
A closed-form approximate solution for the PDE was derived by Zhang and Ge [7] . This they did by using the Prandtl’s assymptotic matching method. the
trick is, first remove the constant term
solve the resulting PDE and call the solution
. Thus
satisfy the PDE
(14)
The second step is to remove the two non linear terms while retaining the non homogeneous term, solve the resulting PDE and call the solution
, thus
satisfy the PDE
(15)
The third step is to factor out the common terms in
and
and call that
. The solution of the original HJB equation will then be given by
(16)
Following [5] and [16] ,
is
(17)
where
and
with
,
,
and
is given by
(18)
where
,
,
and
then becomes
(19)
with
,
,
and
.
The derivatives are given by
(20)
with
,
,
and
(21)
(22)
(23)
(24)
and
(25)
(26)
6. Optimal Investment Policy
Proposition 1. The optimal stock investment policy with the portfolio weight Π is given as (17), (18) and (19)
(27)
Proposition 2. The optimal contribution rate of a PPP strategy is
(28)
with F and
given by (17), (18), (19), (20), (21), and (22)
From proposition (1) and (2) it follows that for optimality of the stock investment and contribution to exist, the following must hold:
1)
2)
. In addition, for
to be positive, then,
and
must not be 0, else
.
The 3D plot for the optimal contribution and optimal stock allocations are given in Figure 1(a) and Figure 1(b) respectively using the following parameters;
,
(a)(b)
Figure 1. (a) Optimal contribution; (b) Optimal stock allocation.
7. Conclusion
This paper considered the optimal investment problem for a pension plan participants in a defined contribution (DC) plan. It was assumed that the interest rate and salary are constant over time and stock price follows a Heston volatility model. The HJB equation was obtained and solved assuming that the CRRA utility function and following the works of [5] and [16] .
Acknowledgements
Manifold thanks to the reviewers.