[1]
|
A. M. Spence, “Job Market Signaling,” Quarterly Jour- nal of Economics, Vol. 87, No. 3, 1981, pp. 355-374.
doi:10.2307/1882010
|
[2]
|
V. Crawford and J. Sobel, “Strategic Information Trans- mission,” Econometrica, Vol. 50, No. 6, 1982, pp. 1431- 1451. doi:10.2307/1913390
|
[3]
|
F. Ederer, “Feedback and Motivation in Dynamic Tour- naments,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, Vol. 19, No. 3, 2010, pp. 733-769.
doi:10.1111/j.1530-9134.2010.00268.x
|
[4]
|
O. Gürtler and C. Harbring, “Feedback in Tournaments under Commitment Problems: Experimental Evidence,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, Vol. 19, No. 3, 2010, pp. 771-810.
doi:10.1111/j.1530-9134.2010.00269.x
|
[5]
|
M. Goltsman and A. Mukherjee, “Interim Performance Feedback in Multistage Tournaments: The Optimality of Partial Disclosure,” Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 29, No. 2, 2011, pp. 229-265. doi:10.1086/656669
|
[6]
|
E.P. Lazear and S. Rosen, “Rank-Order Tournaments as Optimum Labor Contracts,” Journal of Political Econ- omy, Vol. 89, No. 5, 1981, pp. 841-864.
doi:10.1086/261010
|
[7]
|
O. Gürtler, “The First-Order Approach in Rank-Order Tournaments,” Economics Letters, Vol. 111, No.3, 2011, pp. 185-187. doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2011.02.013
|
[8]
|
M. R. Baye, D. Kovenock and C. G. de Vries, “The All- Pay Auction with Complete Information,” Economic The- ory, Vol. 8, No. 2, 1996, pp. 291-305.
|