Environmental Policy for Non-Point Source Pollutions in a Bertrand Duopoly ()
1. Introduction
It is now well-known that most of today’s pollutions such as air pollution, river pollution and lake pollution have multiple sources although any pollution originates from a single point source. It is, however, not known how to control these NPS (non-point source) pollutions. Segarson [2] suggests an ambient charge control: the government adopts an environmental policy to establish a cut-off level of the whole pollution and make the following rule, regardless of each firm’s specific emission level, if the actual level of the total level exceeds the cut-off level, then all firms levy the same penalty while if the actual level falls short of the cut-off level, the all firms are awarded the same subsidy. The main purpose of this study is to demonstrate that the ambient charges can control the total amount of NPS pollutions under ála Bertrand imperfect competition. Based on the analysis of Raju and Ganguli [3] in a Cournot duopoly setting, Matsumoto et al. [4] show a “good-natured” effect of ambient charges in an N-firm Cournot framework that an increase in the ambient charge leads to decreases of the total level of industry pollutions. On the other hand, Ganguli and Raju [1] consider the same subject in a Bertrand duopolistic market and numerically exhibit a “perverse” effect that an increase of ambient charge may lead to an increase in pollution in two distinct settings, one in the one-stage game and the other in the two-stage game. Ishikawa et al. [5] consider an ambient charge effect in an N-firm Bertrand framework. This study shows the good-natured effect of ambient charges in Bertrand duopoly, analytically in one-stage game and numerically in two-stage game.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In section 2, the optimal price strategies of Bertrand duopolistic firms are derived in one-stage game in which all actions take place simultaneously. In Section 3, the optimal choices of abatement technology at the first stage and prices at the second stage are considered in two-stage game in which the actions take place in sequence. Concluding remarks and further extension of this study are given in Section 4.
2. One-Stage Game
In this section we consider the effect of the ambient charge in one stage game in which the regulator has announced the ambient charge and a cut-off ambient standard while two firms have fixed their pollution abatement technologies. Under this circumstance the firms choose their optimal prices to maximize their profits. Each firm produces a differentiated product. Market demand function for firm
for
and
is
(1)
where
denotes good
produced by firm
,
is the price of
,
is the price for the good j and g is a parameter with
measuring the substitutability between two goods.1 We exclude two extreme cases, one with
where the two goods are homogenous and the other with
where they are independent. The total amount of pollution E generated by the two firms is given by
(2)
where
and
represent pollution abatement technologies of firms
and j.
means the worst technology with 100% pollution while
means the best technology with no (0%) pollution. Accordingly, it is assumed that
.
The profit function of firm
is
(3)
where
denotes ambient standard specified by the regulator,
is the production cost where
is the common marginal cost of production and t is an ambient charge or tax with
. According to the spirit of the ambient charge, although the two firms’ contributions to pollutions might be different, each firm will pay the identical fine
if
and receive the identical subsidy
if
. Substituting (1) into (3) and differentiating the resultant profit function with respect to
give the first order condition for an interior solution maximizing profit of firm
,
or
(4)
Maximizing
with respect to
presents a similar first-oder condition for firm j. Hence solving the following simultaneous system, which is obtained from first order conditions for firms
and j,
yields the Bertrand equilibrium prices,
that are, after arranging the terms,
(5)
Concerning the positivity of the Bertrand price, we have the following results.
Theorem 1 If
or if
and
, then
.
Proof. If
holds, then
Then the first equation of (5) implies
. Now suppose that
. If the right hand side of the first equation of (5) is equal to zero, then solving it for
gives the form of
Assumption
implies
Since
for
, the term on the right hand side is greater than unity if
under which, for all
,
The inequality implies that
. Q.E.D.
Differentiating the Bertrand price of firm
with respect to t reveals that the sign of the derivative is the same as the sign of the terms in the square brackets in (5),
Hence the effect caused by a change in the ambient charge on the Bertrand prices can summarized as follows.
Theorem 2 A firm with a larger or equal abatement technology positively responds to a change in the ambient charge whereas the response of a firm with a smaller abatement technology is ambiguous,
Proof. If
, then for firm
, the bracketed terms in (5) are
and for firm j, from the bracketed terms in the second equation of (5) to be equal to zero, we can define the ratio of the abatement technologies
This ratio is less than unity implying
The same procedure can be applied for the case of
. Q.E.D
Substituting the Bertrand prices into the demand functions in (1) presents the Bertrand outputs of firm
and j,
(6)
To check whether
is positive, we subtract the second equation of (6) from the first equation to obtain
(7)
where, in the same way, from (5)
(8)
Concerning the positivity of the Bertrand output, we have the following:
Theorem 3 If
, then
and
for
for
.
Proof. If
holds, then (8) leads to
with which (7) implies
. On the other hand, the first equation of (6) with the forms of
and
given in (5) is reduced to
(9)
where
The direction of the last inequality is due to
and
. Let the numerator of (9) be
. Then due to Descartes’ rule of sign,
has only one positive root,
. Substituting
gives
The last inequality means that
for
, with which then (9) leads to
, implying that
as well. If
, then interchanging the two firms generates the same result. Q.E.D.
Now consider the effect of a change in the ambient charge on each output level.
(10)
Concerning the ambient charge effect on output, we have the following results.
Theorem 4 A firm with a larger or equal abatement technology negatively responds to a change in the ambient charge whereas the response of a firm with a smaller abatement technology is ambiguous:
Proof. If
, then
for
immediately implies the results. If
, then
for
indicates that for firm i,
and for firm j, there is a threshold value of the parameter ratio such as
The same procedure can be applied for the case of
. Q.E.D.
It should be noticed first that firm
with a larger
has an inefficient technology because it generates larger emission. Theorems 2 and 4 imply that, the firm with inefficient technology exhibits natural response to the change in the ambient charge, that is, it increases price and decreases output. On the other hand the firm with efficient technology responds ambiguously. It should be noticed second that these firm-specific responses are non-observable for the regulator which can see only the total amount in the case of NPS pollution.
The total level of pollution at the Bertrand equilibrium is obtained by substituting
and
into (2)
Concerning the effect of a change in the ambient charge on the total pollution, we have the following result.
Theorem 5 An increase in the ambient charge decreases the total level of pollution,
Proof. Differentiating
with respect t gives
Notice that
and the equality holds when
. Hence
Therefore we arrive at the result where the strict inequality is due to the assumption,
. Q.E.D.
Although Theorem 4 implies a possibility of the perverse effect on emission of the individual firm with the efficient abetment technology, Theorem 5 implies that the total effect is always negative, implying that the negative effect of the inefficient firm dominates the positive effect of the efficient firm.
3. Two-Stage Game
In this section the firms and the regulator take actions in two stages. At the first stage, each firm determines its optimal abatement technology whereas the regulator announces the ambient charge and the cut-off level of total pollution. Then at the second stage, the firms choose their prices to maximize their profits, given the ambient charge, the cut-of level and their abatement technologies.
The decision-making at the second stage have been already considered in the one-stage game. Given the Bertrand prices and outputs in (5) and (6), we consider the actions of choosing abatement technology at the first stage. The Bertrand profit function of firm
under Bertrand prices and Bertrand output is defined as
(11)
for
and
. Notice that there is a small difference between the definitions of (3) and (11). There is a term
in (11) and no such a term in (3). This term reflects the cost associated with selecting the abatement technology.2 At the second stage, the abatement technology has been already selected somehow and thus it does not affect the determination of the optimal price whether this cost is included or not. However this cost function is effective for choosing technology at the first stage where the firm
determines its abatement technology,
, so as to maximize its Bertrand profit. Differentiating (11) with respect to
gives the first-order condition for the optimal level of
,
where
Arranging the terms in
with taking account of the forms of the Bertrand prices in (5) yield the modified FOC at the first stage,
(12)
where
In the same way, arranging the terms in
yields the modified FOC for firm j
(13)
Solving (12) and (13) simultaneously for
and
presents the optimal abatement technology for both firms,
(14)
Although the form of the solution seems to be highly complicated, the following result is obtained.
Proposition 1 If
, then the optimal abatement technology
is positive for
and
.
Proof. It is numerically confirmed that the denominator of (14) is negative for
and
. 3 The numerator is rewritten as
(15)
where
Assumption
implies
. The sign of the terms in the braces of (15) is negative for
(i.e.,
) and is also negative for
if
. As the terms satisfies the inequality
and the lower bound of
is 3, then the right hand side is negative for
if
. Thus the sign of the left hand side is also negative. Hence
for
. Therefore (14) with the negative denominator and the negative numerator implies
. Q.E.D.
Notice that the following set is not empty,
implying that the conditions imposed on the values of
and
given in Theorem 3 and Proposition 1 are compatible. Substituting
into the Bertrand prices in (5) gives the optimal Bertrand price
(16)
that is clearly positive for
and
, which is summarized as follows.
Proposition 2 If
, then the optimal Bertrand price
is positive for
and
.
The optimal Bertrand output is obtained by substituting
into the demand function, (1),
(17)
Concerning the optimal output, we can have the following,
Proposition 3
for
and
.
Proof. Substituting
into (14) and (16) present
that is, in turn, substituted into (17) to obtain
then
where the numerator is positive and the denominator is negative. This completes the proof. Q.E.D.
4
and
are taken for this and the following examples. The vertical and horisontal intersecpts of the black curve are
Proposition 3 implies that
is inevitably negative for a small neighborhood of point
. Numerical confirmation of Proposition 3 is given in Figure 1 in which the Bertrand output is negative in the shaded region and positive otherwise.4 The shaded region should be eliminated from further considerations.
![]()
Figure 1. q* > 0 in the white region and q* < 0 in the shaded region.
Finally, the optimal level of total pollution is
(18)
that is apparently negative if
, that is, in the shaded region in Figure 1. Its derivative with respect to t is
(19)
where
and
can be of either sign and thus the sign of the terms in the square bracket seems ambiguous. Numerically, as as shown in Figure 2(a) and Figure 2(b), each derivative is confirmed to be positive in the corresponding shaded region in which
and
in Figure 2(a)
and
and
in Figure 2(b).
The dotted upward-sloping curve in Figure 2(a) is described by the
curve. The shaded region is included in the region with
so that the derivative of the optimal technology is negative in the feasible region with
. Hence the sign of the tax-derivative of the total emission level is definitely negative in the white region in Figure 2(b) as both derivatives are negative. On the other hand, it is sensitive to the relative magnitude between the elasticities of the optimal ambient technology and the optimal output with respect to t in the shaded region in Figure 2(b).
Given the parameter values, Figure 3 illustrates the values of
against a pair of
with
and
. Since it is seen that any point on the 3D surface in Figure 3 is negative, it is numerically shown that
for
and
. According to equation (19), the sign of
is
(a)
(b)
Figure 2. Divisions of the nonnegative (γ, t) region.
![]()
Figure 3. Effective ambient charge under a = 3/2 and c = 1/2.
5We obtain this results with various values of
and
. However, we are unable to prove it analytically so this is an numerically-shown result.
ambiguous in the shaded region of Figure 2(b). However, Figure 3 implies that the elasticity of
in absolute value is larger than that of
, leading to the negative sign of
. Therefore we have our main result that an increase in ambient charge always decreases the total level of optimal pollution.5 We summarize this result.
Proposition 4 It is numerically confirmed that a change in the ambient charge has the good-natured effect,
4. Concluding Remark
In this paper, we reconsider the “perverse” effect caused by a change in ambient charges shown by Ganguli and Raju [1] . To this end, following their basic framework, we first re-examine the effect in one-stage game in which the Bertrand firms determine their prices so as to maximize their profits, given the abatement technology. Our first result analytically demonstrates that an increase of ambient charges decreases the total level of NPS pollutions. We then turn attention to the effect in two-stage game in which the optimal abatement technology is selected at the first stage and the optimal prices are determined at the second stage. Our second result numerically shows the good-natured effect on the total level of pollution. With these results, we conclude that the ambient charge might be an efficient method to control NPS pollutions even in a duopoly Bertrand market.
Funding
The authors highly acknowledge the financial supports from the MEXT-Supported Program for the Strategic Research Foundation at Private Universities 2013-2017, the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science (Grant-in-Aid for Scientific Research (C), 16K03556, 18K01631 and 17H01931) and Chuo University (Joint Research Grant). The usual disclaimer applies.
NOTES
1Intuitively,
and
are substitutes in the following sence that
implies
and
with
implies
Hence to a change in price
the quantity response of good
runs in an opposite direction of the response of good
2See Raju and Ganguli [3] for this cost.
3Numerical calculations of this and any others that follow are done with Mathematica, ver. 11.