[1]
|
G. S. Becker and K. M. Murphy, “A Theory of Rational Addic-tion,” The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 96, No. 4, 1988, pp. 675-700. doi:10.1086/261558
|
[2]
|
G. Becker, “Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach,” The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 76, No. 2, 1968, pp. 169-217. doi:10.1086/259394
|
[3]
|
C. Banks, E. Maloney and H. Wit-trock, “Public Attitudes toward Crime and the Penal System,” British Journal of Criminology, Vol. 15, No. 3, 1975, pp. 228-240.
|
[4]
|
G. Jensen, “Sociology of Delinquency: Current Issues,” Sage, London, 1981.
|
[5]
|
L. Ellis and J. Peterson, “Crime and Religion: An International Comparison among Thirteen Industrial Nations,” Personality and Individual Dif-ferences, Vol. 20, No. 6, 1996, pp. 761-768. doi:10.1016/0191-8869(96)00023-2
|
[6]
|
A. Gaviria, “In-creasing Returns and the Evolution of Violent Crime: The Case of Colombia,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 61, No. 1, 2000, pp. 1-25. doi:10.1016/S0304-3878(99)00059-0
|
[7]
|
W. Pareto, “Cours D′Economie Politique,” Droz, Genève, 1964.
|
[8]
|
A. Marshall, “Principles of Economics,” 8th Edition, Ma- cmillan, New York, 1898.
|
[9]
|
C. Carroll, J. Overland and D. Weil, “Saving and Growth with Habit Formation,” American Economic Review, Vol. 93, No. 3, 2000, pp. 341-355. doi:10.1257/aer.90.3.341
|
[10]
|
E. J. Dockner and G. Feichtinger, “Cyclical Consumption Patterns and Rational Addiction,” American Economic Review, Vol. 83, No. 1, 1993, pp. 256-263.
|
[11]
|
R. Alessie and A. Lusardi, “Consumption, Sav-ing and Habit Formation,” Economics Letters, Vol. 55, No. 1, 1997, pp. 103-108. doi:10.1016/S0165-1765(97)00061-X
|
[12]
|
J. R. Faria and M. León-Ledesma, “Habit Formation, Working Habits and Tech-nological Progress,” Manchester School, Vol. 72, No. 3, 2004, pp. 403-413.
doi:10.1111/j.1467-9957.2004.00399.x
|
[13]
|
T. Ono, “Is Habi-tual Consumption Harmful to the Envi- ronment?” Economics Bulletin, Vol. 17, No. 1, 2002, pp. 1-10.
|
[14]
|
C. Burnside, M. Eichenbaum and J. Fisher, “Fiscal Shocks and Their Conse-quences,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 115, No. 1, 2004, pp. 89-117.
doi:10.1016/S0022-0531(03)00252-7
|
[15]
|
B. McCallum and E. Nelson, “Nominal Income Targeting in an Open-Economy Optimizing Model,” Journal of Mo- netary Economics, Vol. 43, No. 3, 1999, pp. 553-578.
doi:10.1016/S0304-3932(99)00005-7
|
[16]
|
J. Amato and T. Laubach, “Implications of Habit Forma- tion for Optimal Mon-etary Policy,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 51, No. 2, 2004, pp. 305-325.
doi:10.1016/j.jmoneco.2003.05.002
|
[17]
|
I. Ehrlich and F. Lui, “Bureaucratic Corruption and Endogenous Economic Growth,” The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 107, No. S6, 1999, pp. S270-S293.
doi:10.1086/250111
|
[18]
|
V. Teles, “The Effects of Macroe-conomic Policies on Crime,” Economics Bulletin, Vol. 1, No. 1, 2004, pp. 1-9.
|
[19]
|
J. Fender, “A General Equilibrium Model of Crime and Pu- nishment,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, Vol. 39, No. 4, 1999, pp. 437-453.
doi:10.1016/S0167-2681(99)00050-5
|
[20]
|
A. B. Abel, “Asset Prices under Habit Formation and Ca- tching up with the Jo-neses,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 80, No. 2, 1990, pp. 38-42.
|
[21]
|
E. Glaeser and B. Sacerdote, “Why is There More Crime in the Cities?” The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 107, No. S6, 1999, pp. S225-S258. doi:10.1086/250109
|
[22]
|
G. Akerlof and J. Yellen, “Gang Behavior, Law Enfor- cement and Community Values,” In: H. Aaron, T. Mann and T. Taylor, Eds., Values and Public Policy, Brookings Institution Press, Washington D.C., 1994.
|
[23]
|
E. Glaeser, B. Sacerdote and J. Scheinkman, “Crime and Social Interactions,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 111, No. 2, 1996, pp. 507-548. doi:10.2307/2946686
|
[24]
|
F. Car-neiro, P. Loureiro and A. Sachsida, “Crime and So- cial Inte-ractions: A Developing Country Case Study,” The Journal of Socio-Economics, Vol. 34, No. 3, 2005, pp. 311-318. doi:10.1016/j.socec.2004.09.015
|