A Growth Framework Using the Constant Elasticity of Substitution Model ()
1. Introduction
In growth theory, a “production function” is taken to be a mathematical expression that is used to model a production technology with distinct inputs and outputs. Several types of production functions have been proposed in the past based on either empirical or theoretical considerations (for general surveys, see e.g., [1] [2] ). For example, the Cobb-Douglas production function ( [3] ) is widely used as a simple model to study economic growth in spite of some of its limitations (that we shall discuss later).
The CES (“Constant Elasticity of Substitution”) function was introduced by Solow ( [4] ), and later expounded by Arrow et al. ( [5] ) to synthesize several types of production functions. The CES function has been applied extensively to study economic growth (e.g., [6] - [17] ). It has also applications in high energy physics [18] . Many generalizations of the format of the CES function (including the multi-input case) have been proposed, for details see e.g. [6] [7] . The shape of the frontier of the CES function is also of significant interest in economic analysis and its connection with the differential geometry of hyperspaces has been studied. (e.g., [19] [20] [21] ).
The elasticity of substitution between any two input variables in a production function measures how easily one variable can be substituted for the other variable and it measures the curvature of the isoquant (the concept was first introduced by Hicks [22] ). So, an elasticity of substitution equal to 0 indicates no substitution between the input variables can be possible and an elasticity of substitution equal to infinity indicates the perfect substitution. More formally, the elasticity of substitution between two factors of production is an index that measures the percentage of response of the relative marginal products of the two factors to a percentage of change in the ratio of the two quantities. In order to make the paper self-contained, we shall briefly review in Appendix I the formal definition of the elasticity of substitution for the case of a production function with n input variables.
For the Cobb-Douglas function the elasticity of substitution between the input variables is always equal to 1 (for a proof see, e.g., [7] ) and this fact restricts its use as a suitable production model in several applications, as claimed by many authors. For example, Antrás [23] has shown that the US economy is not amenable to the elasticity of substitution being taken as 1. Also Werf [24] has shown that it is not suitable to take the Cobb-Douglas function as a production function for modeling climate change policies. Furthermore, Young [25] has shown that the elasticity of substitution for U.S. aggregate and of most industries cannot be equal to 1 and it is estimated to be less than 0.620; thus it follows that the Cobb-Douglas production model (whose elasticity of substitution is fixed to be 1) is not suitable for such applications.
The CES function has a constant elasticity of substitution (as the name suggests) and it can have any pre-determined value as its elasticity of sub-stitution (as we shall show later). Thus, it offers a wider flexibility than the Cobb-Douglas function and is still computationally tractable, as remarked in ( [6] , p. 54). These reasons have partially motivated us to extend some results of the neoclassical growth theory based on the Cobb-Douglas function by using the more general setting of the CES production function.
We now briefly review some definitions and results.
Definition 1 ( [5] ) The Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) production function for the three factors-capital K, labor L and the total factor of productivity F, is given by
(1)
where Y is the output and
are smooth functions of time t;
is a certain constant, called the share parameter between the capital and labor; and
is another constant, called the substitution parameter.
The following result indicates that the CES production function is a generalization of the Cobb-Douglas function:
Proposition 1 ( [5] ) When
, the CES production function (1) approaches the Cobb-Douglas production function
(2)
where
are constants such that
.
It is known that the elasticity of substitution of the CES production function as defined by (1), is equal to
( [5] , p. 230) when
, and using this result we can easily construct (as indicated in Example 1) an infinite family of CES production functions each of whose members has the same elasticity of substitution equal to any given nonzero number.
Example 1 Suppose we want to construct a CES production function whose elasticity of substitution,
, is equal to, say, 2. Solving the equation
(3)
gives
. Substituting
into (1) and taking F to be any smooth function of t, and by varying
, we get an infinite family of CES production functions given by
(4)
where
and each member of the family has the same elasticity of substitution equal to 2. Similarly, if
, then by solving the equation
we get
and this corresponds to the Cobb-Douglas production function (compare with Proposition 1).
In defining the CES production function, in the form given by (1), many authors take F to be a parameter (e.g., [5] , p. 230; [7] , p. 397; [26] , p. 397). However, we shall consider here a more general model where F is assumed to be a function of time. Such a model would be able to handle some situations that cannot be accommodated by a CES function where F is a parameter. For example, the output of a factory may increase at a time when the production manager is replaced by a more efficient one (i.e. when F increases) even when there are no increases in investments in capital and labor. We note that ( [6] , p. 54) takes F to be a function of time, like us. Furthermore we shall exclude the cases when the output is either identically zero, or a negative number as these cases are not of interest. Thus we make the following assumption:
Assumption 1 We assume in (1) that F is a function of time and that
.
As remarked in ( [27] , p. 107), the wages and salaries in USA and many other countries form about 70 percent of the national income. Consequently, the value of
has been used in ( [27] , p. 107-109) as the share of the capital for the Cobb-Douglas production function model (2) to estimate the growth rate for a number of countries. However, such an estimate for the growth rate of countries based solely on a Cobb-Douglas production function model may not be realistic because the Cobb-Douglas production function (2) has the unitary elasticity of substitution and as [23] has shown, it is not suitable to model the US economy with the elasticity of substitution equal to 1 (also, it is not known whether we can realistically assume that the elasticity of substitution is 1 for all the other countries involved in that study). So, it would be of significant interest to estimate the economic growth for various countries using the same data but for a more general setting involving the CES production function model for a range of values of the parameter
in (1) with
, and then to estimate an optimal value of
to fit the data set.
The structure of the rest of the paper is as follows. In Section 2 we obtain a growth equation for the CES production function and define the (generalized) Solow residual and the corresponding capital deepening term. In Section 3 we obtain some bounds for the (generalized) Solow residual and the capital deepening term. In Section 4 we investigate the growth rates corresponding to the CES production function. In Section 5 we investigate the homogeneous property of the CES production function. Section 6 gives our conclusions. Appendix I reviews the definition of the elasticity of substitution, The proofs of all the results are given in the Appendix II.
2. Growth Equation for CES Production Model
In this section, we generalize some results obtained earlier in the setting of the Cobb-Douglas production model (e.g., as in [27] , Chap. 5) to the case of the CES production function. First, we shall derive a growth equation corresponding to the CES production function. Continuing with the notation introduced in Definition 1, we now define the variables y and k given by
(5)
where we assume that L is nonzero (for, if
, the CES production function takes the simple form
and that is a special case of the Cobb-Douglas function with
and
; and so we omit this case). Thus, y and k are well-defined and y represents the output per worker (i.e., per capita output) and k is the capital stock per worker. Also, L cannot be negative because we have not given any interpretation to negative labor. So, we shall make the following assumption:
Assumption 2
We assume that
.
We note that ( [6] , p. 36) also makes a similar assumption.
From (1), dividing both sides of the equation by L, and using (5), we get
(6)
Log differentiating both sides of (6) with respect to t and denoting
by G, we get the following growth equation when the CES production function is taken as the production model:
(7)
where
denotes differentiation with respect t. Both the terms on the right hand side of (7) are well-defined because their denominators are nonzero (F is nonzero by the Assumption 1, and
is nonzero since otherwise it will follow from (6) that
and we shall exclude this trivial case when the output is identically equal to zero); also G is well-defined (since otherwise from the expression
, it will follow that
).
Taking the limit as
in (7) and using Proposition 1, we can easily obtain the growth equation corresponding to the Cobb-Douglas production function (2) and the resulting equation matches with the corresponding Equation (5.3) derived in ( [27] , p. 106).
Definition 2 For the CES production function, the expression
(8)
is called the growth rate of the output per worker, and the growth rate of the total factor of productivity,
, will be called the Solow residual corresponding to the CES production function.
Using (7), the Solow residual can be expressed as:
(9)
where
(10)
is called the capital deepening term corresponding to the CES production function. From (9), we observe that G, the growth rate of the output per worker, is the sum of two components: (i) the Solow residual, and (ii) the capital deepening component D (we note that a similar observation is made for the Cobb-Douglas production function (2), in ( [27] , p. 106)).
Next, we consider the form of the growth equation (7) in the steady state.
Proposition 2 (i) When a steady state of production is reached, the growth rate of the output per worker is equal to the Solow residual, and the capital deepening term is zero. As a partial converse, if the production is not entirely labor intensive, a steady state of production is reached when the growth rate of the output per worker is equal to the Solow residual (or equivalently when the capital deepening term is zero).
(ii) The total factor of productivity is in a steady state if and only if the growth rate of the output per worker is equal to the capital deepening term.
3. Estimates for Solow Residual
We now obtain some bounds for the capital deepening term D and the Solow residual.
Proposition 3 For the CES production function given by (6), if the ratio of the share parameters is less than
, i.e. if
(11)
then (i) the capital deepening term is less than the growth rate of capital per worker, and
(ii) the Solow residual is greater than the difference between the growth rates per worker, of the output and the capital.
Corollary 1 (i) When
, the estimates given in Proposition 3 hold for any
.
(ii) When
, (i.e., when the production function is approaching the Cobb-Douglas function (2), see Proposition 1), the estimates given in Proposition 3 hold for any
.
We now give some examples to illustrate what happens to the inequality (11) as we progressively increase the value of
.
Example 2 (i) Suppose, as an illustration, we choose
and so
. In Figure 1, we plot the values of
where the horizontal axis corresponds to
and the vertical axis corresponds to u. We know from Corollary 1 (i) that as
becomes larger and larger, the value of u would tend to 1 and this property is being exhibited in Figure 1. We mention that similar illustrations can also be given by taking other values of
.
(ii) If
(that is, when the capital and labor are shared equally in the CES production model), the condition (11) reduces to
and so the estimates described in Proposition 3 hold for any
and for any value of
. In other words, when the distributions of resources between the capital and labor in the production are equal and the capital stock per worker is greater than one, the results of Proposition 3 hold for any value of
.
Now we obtain further interpretations of the estimates that were given in Proposition 3.
Proposition 4 For any set of values of
and k satisfying the condition
![]()
Figure 1. Plot of
against
.
(11), the estimates given in Proposition 3 would continue to hold when we keep increasing the value of either,
or, k.
4. Marginal Rate of Substitution
For any arbitrary production function with output Y and the factors of production, K, L and F, the marginal products with respect to the capital, labor and the factor of productively are defined as
,
and
respectively. Also, the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) is defined as the ratio of the marginal product with respect to the capital by the marginal product with respect to labor, i.e.,
(12)
We now consider the growth of the marginal products with respect to the three factors appearing in the CES production function.
Proposition 5
For the CES production function, the marginal products with respect to all the three factors of production are increasing functions of time. Further, the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) is given by
(13)
We note that (13) is well defined since by Assumption 2 we have
and so
. It follows from (13) that the MRS is independent of both the total factor of productivity and the output per worker. Also, for
, (13) implies that
as
. For
, (13) implies that
as
.
For the Cobb-Douglas function (2), the marginal rate of substitution can be easily obtained by taking the limit as
in (13) and using Proposition 1; and the result thus obtained matches with the corresponding expression in ( [27] , p. 107).
5. Homogeneity of CES Function and Wages
We recall the standard definition that a function
of n independent variables
is a homogenous function of degree k if
for any positive scalar t. A classical theorem due to L. Euler (1703-1783) on homogeneous functions (see, e.g., [28] for a proof) states that if
is a homogeneous function of degree k with continuous partial derivatives then
(14)
Now, it is easy to see that the CES production function, given by (1), is a homogeneous function of degree 2 in the variables K, L and F. So, from (14) with
and
and writing Y for f, we have
(15)
Using (15) we now obtain a result for the wage of a worker in the context of the CES production function model (the result is closely along the lines of ( [29] , p. 7), Equation (15)):
Proposition 6 Assume that in the short run the relative price of the factors adjust so that capital and labor are fully employed. Then, for the CES production function, the wage of a worker is equal to the balance remaining from the output per worker when we spend the rental price of capital times the capital per worker (assuming that there is no wage differentiation, i.e. all the workers receive the same wages).
We remark that if F is a constant (in temporary contravention of Assumption 1), then the degree of homogeneity of the CES function is unity, and the Euler’s theorem on homogeneous function (14) now gives (compare with (15))
(16)
and it is easy to verify that the statement of Proposition 6 still holds for this case by rearranging slightly the proof of Proposition 6.
6. Conclusion
We have extended some results of the neoclassical growth theory when the production function is taken to be the CES function instead of the Cobb- Douglas function. Such generalizations are of considerable interest because the Cobb-Douglas function is not suitable for some application areas because its elasticity of substation has always the fixed value 1 whereas a CES function can be designed to have any pre-determined value as its elasticity of substitution. We assume that the total factor of productivity is a variable instead of being a parameter and under this assumption the CES production function becomes a homogenous function of degree two, and so it gives increasing returns to scale. When the total factor of productivity is steady, we show that the growth rate is equal to the Solow residual. We obtain some estimates of the Solow residual and the capital deepening term. We show that when the production is not entirely capital-intensive, an increase in capital implies an increase in the ratio of the production rate. We have considered here a CES production function where the input variables are the capital, labor and the total factor of productivity; and it would be of interest to extend our results to the more general cases of several input variables and also several output variables.
APPENDIX I: Elasticity of Substitution-Review
We briefly review here the definition of the elasticity of substitution (for further details see, e.g., [6] [7] ). Consider a general production function with output Y given by
(17)
where
(
) are some independent variables and f is an arbitrary function that is differentiable partially with respect to each of the variables
. The elasticity of substitution
between any two distinct variables
and
measures the percentage of response of the relative marginal products of the two factors to a percentage of change in the ratio of the two quantities. It is defined as (e.g., [29] , p. 509):
(18)
along the curve
where
is a constant; the logarithm being taken to the base e (i.e., the natural logarithm). For the CES production function, (17) takes the form given by (1) with
and
to be the variables
respectively. For the CES function, it can be shown ( [5] ) that
(19)
when we take
to be any two of the variables
.
APPENDIX II: Proofs
1) Proof of Proposition 2:
(i) In the steady state,
, and we get from (7) that
. Also, when
, we get from (10) that
.
For the partial converse, we note that if the growth rate is equal to the rate of the total factor of productivity, i.e. if
, then we get from (7) and (10) that
(20)
and (20) implies that
because both
and k are nonzero by our assumptions; also
is nonzero since otherwise from (6) we would get
and this would imply from (5) that
, a trivial case.
(ii) It follows from (9) that the total factor of productivity is in a steady state (i.e.,
) if and only if
.
2) Proof of Proposition 3:
From (10) on expanding by Taylor’s theorem and stopping after one term, we have as a linear approximation
(21)
provided
; or, equivalently, provided (11) holds (here
denotes approximately). Now, the condition
can be expressed as:
(22)
Thus, from (21) and (22) we get
(23)
provided (11) holds. This proves (i).
(We remark that if instead of a linear approximation, we had taken a second degree approximation from (10), i.e. had stopped after the second term in the Taylor’s expansion (21), then it is easy to verify that we would obtain the same result (23) provided (11) holds; we omit the details.)
Using (9) and (23) we get
(24)
provided (11) holds. This proves (ii).
3) Proof of Corollary 1:
(i) When
, we have
for a fixed value of
, and the inequality (11) reduces to
. (ii) When
, we have that
and (11) gives
, i.e.,
since
.
4) Proof of Proposition 4:
If
are any two non-zero values, then it is easy to see that for a given non-zero value of
, we have
implies that
(25)
It follows from (25) that for any
,
(26)
So, once the inequality (11) holds for a certain set of values of
, k, and
, the estimates (23)-(24) in the statement of Proposition 3 would continue to hold if we keep on increasing the value of
while keeping
fixed. Further, if we increase the value of k, the estimates (23)-(24) would still hold.
5) Proof of Proposition 5:
From (1) we get after some simplifications
(27)
If the production is not entirely labor intensive, then
and K are not identically zero (also
by the Assumption 1); so it follows from (27) that
; thus the production rate with respect to capital is increasing. Similarly,
(28)
By the Assumption 2, the production is not entirely capital-intensive, and so
and
. We thus have from (28) that
; thus the production rate with respect to labor is increasing (note that by the Assumption 2,
).
Again, we get that
(29)
since otherwise
, a trivial case that we exclude (recall that
by the Assumption 1). Thus the production rate with respect to the total factor of productivity is also increasing. From (27) and (28) we now obtain
(30)
and this proves (13).
6) Proof of Proposition 6:
Assuming that the capital and labor are fully employed, in the short run the wage is given by
. Also, we have
(31)
So, (15) can be written as
(32)
and rewriting (32) by using (5), we get
(33)
and this implies that in the short run, the wage of a worker is equal to the balance remaining from the output per worker when we spend the rental price of capital times the capital per worker since y is the output per worker and
is the rental price and k is the capital stock per worker. This proves the result.