Local Taxation, Private-Public Consumption Complementarity, and the Optimal Number of Jurisdictions ()
1. Introduction
In so far as the optimal local public goods provision-tax rate mix is concerned, the Tiebout [1] hypothesis maintains that citizens accommodate their preferences for this mix by “foot voting” or the same, through interjurisdictional migration, i.e. by settling down each to his or her most preferred jurisdiction, with the optimal number of communities being shaped by this sorting out of citizen preferences. In so far as the mix regarding local private goods supply-tax rates is concerned, the confrontation of wasteful interjurisdictional tax competition to attract private capital presupposes a limited only number of localities at the Nash-Cournot equilibrium (Hoyt [2] ). The same result obtains when “the levels of taxation and the local public good varieties provided within jurisdictions are selected by majority voting” (Perroni and Scharf [3] ). Which is then the optimal number of localities, the one that would not change in response to tax competition?
Assuming that the relevant tax is that on capital, this question translates to finding the capital tax structure across communities, which would not induce burgher relocation, and from which no community would have an incentive to deviate. Private investments in a locality create jobs and incomes to be consumed while public expenditures by a locality aim at satisfying burgher demand for the goods provided through them. Evoking upon the complementarity between private and public consumption in the sense of private consumption responding positively to an increase in public spending (Fiorito and Kollintzas [4] , Linnemann [5] , Bouakez and Rebei [6] , Ganelli and Tervala [7] ), this paper maintains that the optimum tax is simply the one which maximizes the individual utility from these two consumption types on the proviso that this is the aim of local governments as well. Much more so when complementarity (as opposed to substitutability) is certainly the case with the public goods that are rival in consumption and whose positive externalities depend on distributional and demographic characteristics as is this case with the local public goods.
From still another point of view, as soon as term “public consumption” refers to consumption of public goods and hence, to the public investments made to produce them, we do know from Ogura and Yohe [8] originally and Bucci and Del Bo [9] more recently that public and private capital complement each other. At the local level, this implies that a local public project is expected to raise the productivity of the private industry situated in the same locality. Taxes are a distortion but under capital complementarity, an underinvestment by the private sector may be counterbalanced by public investment raising the marginal product of private capital and encouraging thereby the inflow of such capital. The subsequent public investment externalities-spillovers at the general equilibrium setting are expected, following Figuières et al. [10] , to have subsided at interjurisdictional equilibrium while interjurisdictional cooperation to increase growth rates should be sought only if the consumption preferences regarding “domestic and foreign goods” allow so.
In what follows, what is done analytically is to merge Hoyt’s [2] model of the local finances with Ganelli and Tervala’s [7] approach to private-public consumption complementarity. What we find then is that foot voting and tax competition become extinct when the tax structure across jurisdictions is the one forging close local ties for the burgher. These are ties shaped by the private-public consumption complementarity despite different tastes in a given community. The intuitive appeal of this result is then contemplated within the broader framework of fiscal policymaking accommodative of citizen heterogeneity. Complementarity allows communities to handle efficiently heterogeneity in preferences, leaving endowment differences to be dealt with by the state.
2. The Model
We shall first model the locality in line with Hoyt [2] to combine it next with the modeling of the burgher following Ganelli and Tervala [7] .
2.1. The Locality
A single private good is assumed to be produced in a given locality, which is providing a single public good, based both production processes on mobile labor and capital. Let the local government budget constraint be
(1)
where
is the tax per laborer
on the capital
of the th jurisdiction providing the local public good
. The ratio
gives the mix of public and private investment in
. Abstracting from differences in the production technologies used locally, jurisdictional output per capita is
or
, but total capital
(2)
and labor
are fixed so that total per capita output
is given too. Free
movement of capital and labor implies equalization across jurisdictions of the rate of return
on capital so that
(3)
in each locality. From (2) one obtains that
(4)
being presumably the market share of jurisdiction 1, while
is the derivative of the
th jurisdiction’s demand for capital with respect to the price
of capital at equilibrium. So, if there are two only jurisdictions, 1 and 2, the movement of capital from 1 to 2 in response to a tax increase in 1 will be captured by
(5)
and
(6)
Consequently, from (1) and (5),
![]()
or noticing that the elasticity of the demand for
is
,
(7)
where
. Finally, private consumption per capita
is given by
(8)
where the last term is capital income;
. From (8) and (3) one obtains that
(9)
which when combined with (7), yields that
(10)
2.2. The Burgher
Eichner and Runkel [11] argue that “If the capital supply elasticity is strictly positive,… capital tax rates are inefficiently low in… decentralized equilibrium.” This should not be the case under general equilibrium, prompting in turn a discussion of the burgher as follows. Let the utility function of the typical citizen of the th jurisdiction be
![]()
where ln denotes the natural logarithm, the coefficient
is positive, capturing the complementarity between
and
, (an increase in
increases the marginal utility of
given the negative sign accompanying the positive
), while the parameter
gives the elasticity of the marginal disutility of producing
with respect to
. The disutility of producing
in a given jurisdiction
refers to the deviation from the optimal capital-labor ratio following labor relocation.
and
reflect the burgher’s attitude towards local public goods and private capital, respectively. Letting
be the equilibrium price level,
(11)
where
(12)
as it obtains from the household maximization problem given the budget constraint
![]()
where
satisfies of course (1), i.e. local budgets are assumed to be balanced. That is,
(13)
meaning that the disutility from trying to restore the optimal local capital-labor ratio following say emigration from a locality, should be equal to the utility derived from the consumption of one more unit produced towards the restoration of the ratio. Log-linearized, (13) becomes
, which in view of the equilibrium relationship
, yields that
(14)
2.3. Analysis
Now, note that from (14),
(15)
which when combined with (10) gives that
(16)
in so far as jurisdiction 1 is concerned. Solving (16) for
and differentiating with respect to
, the derivative
will be zero, i.e. changes in
will have no effect on
as should be the case at equilibrium, iff
(17)
This in conjunction with (1) imply that one property of the optimal tax structure should be that
(18)
Or, inserting (14) in
, gives that
![]()
which by (1) implies that
(19)
Note that from (17) or (18),
iff
, and hence,
. A third expression for
is obtained by inserting (17) in (8) given also (1):
(20)
This is a more complicated expression but it does suggest that
is too a condition for
. And, since
, a third condition is that
. This coupled with the restriction that
, implies that both
and
should exceed 1.
In words, foot voting becomes meaningless if the burgher “feels” much attached to the local entrepreneurial activity and tax competition becomes futile if the burger feels the same attached to the local public goods supplied by its jurisdiction. And, the complementarity between private and public consumption ensures that “the two feelings” work in the same direction, which the interjurisdictional tax structure comes to exploit in order maximize attachment and minimize subsequently migration and capital flight. Two burghers differing in tastes may be feeling the same attachment to a given locality, which is this attachment that according to (18), (19), or (20) should be the target of policy, not the satisfaction of individual preferences per se.
3. Concluding Remarks
The nonlinearity, the Mirrleesian character of the optimal tax structure across jurisdictions prompts one to think of this structure as a decentralized fiscal vehicle accommodating heterogeneity in
’s and
’s. It is a vehicle that cannot be provided by the central government but which comes to complement the da Costa-Werning Mirrleesian framework in which the central government can accommodate the differences in earning ability (Gahvari and Micheletto [12] ). There are the advantages of such a scheme: First, localities are absolved from redistributive tasks, which may certainly become responsible for regional shifts in population and economic activity (see e.g. Bahl [13] ). Local taxation in the sense developed earlier, can be optimal only from the viewpoint of allocational objectives, i.e. of influencing the geographical pattern of private investment and determining the level and mix of local public goods expenditure. Second, the framework of national-subnational government interaction becomes well defined, assigning the redistributive and stabilization objectives exclusively to the state and minimizing the need for central authority intervention in the local finances. And third, the proposed scheme weakens further the need to take recourse to the redistributive power of monetary policy and thereby to decisionmaking on the part of a non-elected central banker.
Of course, it all depends on whether private consumption and government spending are actually positively related or not. This is a matter of ongoing theoretical and empirical investigation, which appears to confirm this hypothesis and needs to expand to local finance as well. What our discussion herein suggests towards this direction is that the close burgher-community ties may be a reason for the external habit formation contemplated for example by Ravn, Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe [14] . Note that it has been a discussion assuming away public-good and factor congestion and the need for such local taxation on mobile firms and households that would internalize marginal crowding costs. Once the matter of congestion is addressed, our conclusions here would continue holding if this first-best local policymaking was possible, and they would be strengthened even further in a second- best setting, because as Wellisch and Hülshorst [15] emphasize, the second-best is one in which: “[M]igration does not only reveal the preferences for local public goods, as suggested by Tiebout [1] . Rather, local governments have incentives to consider these preferences in a socially efficient way even if they only rely on distortionary taxes”.
We conclude this brief essay by noting that at this abstract level of our discussion, only a qualitative description of the optimal number of jurisdictions has been provided; numerical calibrations would certainly produce definite results, but would depend on the market size assumed, which is one aspect of the issue under investigation that is being researched by itself (see e.g. Casella [16] , Casella and Feinstein [17] ). Another limitation of the calibration would be the absence analytically of a differentiation between first- and second-order administrative subdivisions, between say provinces and municipalities, respectively, which is an issue addressed only recently by Auffhammer and Carson [18] . Finally, only one tax is assumed as policy instrument available to localities while the presence of matching grants on the part of central government to correct for interjurisdictional spillovers (Figuières and Hindriks [19] , Hoyt [20] ) is disregarded, too.
Acknowledgements
I am grateful to an anonymous referee for useful comments and suggestions.