Static Aspect of Heterogeneous Competition in Duopoly

Abstract

The study gives a comparison between price policy and quantity policy in duopoly producing differentiated goods with different production costs and indicates which is more beneficial. Further, it is investigated that in a non-linear duopoly with differentiated goods and two different policies, firms may earn more profit if they choose a quantity policy in a stable economy when the marginal production cost of both the firms is the same. If the production cost of both firms is different, then the price policy is better only when the firm is efficient.

Share and Cite:

Kapoor, B. (2022) Static Aspect of Heterogeneous Competition in Duopoly. Open Journal of Applied Sciences, 12, 455-468. doi: 10.4236/ojapps.2022.124031.

1. Introduction

There are mainly two types of market systems, one is Monopoly and the other is Perfect Competition and they are completely contrary to each other in character [1] [2]. Cournot proposed a new market system named Oligopoly [3]. Oligopoly is the transitional case of monopoly and perfect competition [4] [5]. Duopoly is the sub-case of oligopoly. A duopoly is a market system that is controlled by two firms. There are two classical models in the theory of duopoly. One is of Cournot and the other is of Bertrand [6]. Both mentioned models firms were generating the same kind of goods and adopting homogeneous strategies. Cournot model firms use quantity strategies while Bertrand model firms use price strategies [7] [8]. Numerous researchers have established mathematical models to deal with diverse situations of duopoly [9] [10]. In most established studies, researchers assumed that in a duopoly, both firms produce homogeneous goods and adopt the same kind of strategy either quantity strategy or price strategy [11] [12]. But in real-life situations, firms may produce different kinds of products which provide customers a variety of goods to choose from them and it provides opportunities for firms to improve their products because of competition. Also, it is not necessary that both firms adopt homogeneous strategies [13]. Instead, in order to get maximum benefit and avail market situations, firms use different strategies. Various studies have been conducted to give a realistic outlook to the classical model [14] [15]. Many theories are established on the idea of product differentiation [16] [17] as well. Some researchers established the relation between relative profit objective and the advertising competition model [18] [19]. But, there is not abundant work on the non-linear duopoly model with the heterogeneous cost of production and heterogeneous strategies. In this paper, the strategic behavior in a heterogeneous nonlinear differentiated duopoly is observed. For this, a duopoly model is examined after introducing nonlinearity through heterogeneous strategies and differentiated goods while the cost of production of both firms is also heterogeneous. The main objective of the paper is to analyze the static effect of non-linearity on the behavior of the competitors. Non-linearity in the duopoly model is due to various reasons like heterogeneity in production cost, heterogeneity in strategy, and heterogeneity in competition, which means that different firms choose different strategies. This paper is systematized like this: In Section 2, there is an outline of the general demand function in dissimilar duopoly; Section 3 describes the differentiated duopoly with linear demand function; Section 4 explains the duopoly with non-linear demand with heterogeneous stratagems as well as heterogeneous manufacturing cost and a conclusion is given in Section 5.

2. Duopoly with General Demand Function

As in a duopoly, two firms compete against each other. So, let there be two firms firm 1 and firm 2. Let us suppose that firm 1 produces x 1 quantity of a product with price p x 1 and firm 2 produces x 2 quantity of product with price p x 2 . The motive of both firms is to earn maximum profit. Let us consider the case when both players follow heterogeneous strategy. In that case, one of the players follows quantity strategy taking price variable of other as given and other follows price strategy taking quantity variable of other firm as given. In other words, one of the players follows Cournot and the other Bertrand. From here forth, we write CB competition, if the first player follows Cournot and second Bertrand competition. Similarly, BC competition indicates that the first firm follows Bertrand competition and the other Cournot. The inverse demand function [20] is given by

p x 1 = f ( x 1 , x 2 ) ,

p x 2 = g ( x 1 , x 2 )

Above equation can also be written as

x 1 = f 1 ( p x 1 , x 2 ) (2.1)

x 2 = g 1 ( x 1 , p x 2 ) (2.2)

If c 1 and c 2 are marginal production costs of firm 1 and firm 2 respectively, their corresponding profits are

π x 1 = ( p x 1 c 1 ) x 1 (2.3)

π x 2 = ( p x 2 c 2 ) x 2 (2.4)

In CB competition, firm 1 is quantity setter and firm 2 is price setter. So, variables are x 1 and p x 2 . Therefore, rewriting Equations (2.3) and (2.4), we get

π x 1 = ( f ( x 1 , x 2 ) c 1 ) x 1

π x 1 = f ( f ( x 1 , g 1 ( x 1 , p x 2 ) ) c 1 ) x 1

π x 1 = Π x 1 ( x 1 , p x 2 )

and

π x 2 = ( g ( x 1 , x 2 ) c 2 ) x 2

π x 2 = g ( g ( x 1 , g 1 ( x 1 , p x 2 ) ) c 2 ) g 1 ( x 1 , p x 2 )

π x 2 = Π x 2 ( x 1 , p x 2 )

Thus, profit in CB competition of both the firms is a function of two variables, where quantity is variable for the first firm and price for the second firm, as both the firms want to earn maximum profit. For that take partial derivatives of these profit functions w.r.t x 1 and p x 2 respectively and then equate to zero. Reaction functions are obtained by solving these equations for value of x 1 and p x 2 for which profit is maximum. Moreover, these values of x 1 and p x 2 give CB equilibrium [20]. Similarly, in BC competition, firm 1 is the price setter and firm 2 is quantity setter. Value of x 1 is substituted in Equations (2.3) and (2.4) respectively as follows:

π x 1 = ( f ( x 1 , x 2 ) c 1 ) x 1

π x 1 = ( f ( f 1 ( p x 1 , x 2 ) , x 2 ) c 1 ) f 1 ( p x 1 , x 2 )

π x 1 = Π x 1 ( p x 1 , x 2 )

and

π x 2 = ( g ( x 1 , x 2 ) c 2 ) x 2

π x 2 = ( g ( f 1 ( p x 1 , x 2 ) , x 2 ) c 2 ) x 2

π x 2 = Π x 2 ( p x 1 , x 2 )

As discussed above, take partial derivatives of these profit functions w.r.t. p x 1 and x 2 respectively and then equate to zero. Reaction functions are obtained by solving these equations for values of p x 1 and x 2 for which profit is maximum. Moreover, these values of p x 1 and x 2 give BC equilibrium.

3. Differentiated Duopoly Model with Linear Demand Function

Here we consider that both the firms are dealing in differentiated goods. Let θ 1 be the measure of extent to which product of both firms differentiate. Linear inverse demand function is given by

p x 1 = p m x 1 θ 1 x 2 (3.1)

p x 2 = p m θ 1 x 1 x 2 (3.2)

where p m denotes the maximum price firms want to gain, θ 1 = 1 means that goods are perfect substitutes and θ 1 = 0 means independent products. Here we take assumption that 0 < θ 1 < 1 [21]. Now we want to find CB equilibrium and maximum profits of both the firms. So, we need to find the values of x 1 and x 2 from Equations (3.1) and (3.2). For this multiply Equation (3.2) by θ 1 and subtract from (3.1), which gives

( 1 θ 1 2 ) x 1 = ( 1 θ 1 ) p m p x 1 + θ 1 p x 2

x 1 = 1 1 θ 1 2 [ ( 1 θ 1 ) p m p x 1 + θ 1 p x 2 ] (3.3)

Similarly, Multiplying (3.1) by θ 1 and subtract from (3.2), which gives

( 1 θ 1 2 ) x 2 = ( 1 θ 1 ) p m + θ 1 p x 1 p x 2

x 2 = 1 1 θ 1 2 [ ( 1 θ 1 ) p m + θ 1 p x 1 p x 2 ] (3.4)

As in CB competition x 1 and p x 2 are the variables. So, eliminate x 2 from Equations (3.1) by substituting value of x 2 from (3.2)

p x 1 = p m x 1 θ 1 ( p m θ 1 x 1 p x 2 )

p x 1 = ( 1 θ 1 ) p m ( 1 θ 1 2 ) x 1 + θ 1 p x 2 (3.5)

π x 1 = ( p x 1 c 1 ) x 1 (3.6)

by using Equation (3.5), Equation (3.6) reduces to

π x 1 = ( ( 1 θ 1 ) p m ( 1 θ 1 2 ) x 1 + θ 1 p x 2 c 1 ) x 1 (3.7)

Also, by using Equation (2.4), we have

π x 2 = ( p x 2 c 2 ) x 2

Further, using Equation (3.4), we get

π x 2 = ( p x 2 c 2 ) 1 1 θ 1 2 { ( 1 θ 1 ) p m + θ 1 p x 1 p x 2 }

π x 2 = 1 1 θ 1 2 p x 2 ( 1 θ 1 ) p m + θ 1 p x 1 p x 2 1 θ 1 2 1 1 θ 1 2 ( p x 2 ) 2 c 2 ( 1 θ 1 ) p m + θ 1 p x 1 p x 2 1 θ 1 2

Substituting value of p x 1 from Equation (3.5) in π x 2 , we get

π x 2 = p x 2 ( 1 θ 1 ) p m 1 θ 1 2 + θ 1 ( ( 1 θ 1 ) p m x 1 ( 1 θ 1 2 ) + θ 1 p x 2 ) p x 2 1 θ 1 2 1 1 θ 1 2 ( p x 2 ) 2 c 2 [ ( 1 θ 1 ) p m + θ 1 ( ( 1 θ 1 ) p m x 1 ( 1 θ 1 2 ) + θ 1 p x 2 ) p x 2 ] 1 θ 1 2 (3.8)

Now from Equations (3.7) and (3.8), it is clear that π x 1 and π x 2 are functions of variables x 1 and p x 2 . So, reactions functions can be obtained by taking

π x 1 x 1 = 0

and

π x 2 p x 2 = 0

we get

( 1 θ 1 ) p m 2 ( 1 θ 1 2 ) x 1 + θ 1 p x 2 c 1 = 0 (3.9)

1 1 θ 1 2 ( 1 θ 1 ) p m + 1 1 θ 1 2 { θ 1 ( ( 1 θ 1 ) p m x 1 ( 1 θ 1 2 ) + 2 θ 1 p x 2 ) } 2 p x 2 1 θ 1 2 c 2 [ ( θ 1 ) 2 1 ] 1 θ 1 2 = 0

p m θ 1 x 1 2 p x 2 + c 2 = 0 (3.10)

If we consider the case that production cost of both firms is positive and same i.e. homogeneous production cost. Take c 1 and c 2 both zero, and this is typical postulation of linear models. Solving reaction functions given in Equations (3.9) and (3.10) simultaneously, we get equilibrium output in CB competition.

( 2 θ 1 ) p m = ( 4 3 θ 1 2 ) x 1

x 1 = ( 2 θ 1 ) p m 4 3 θ 1 2 (3.11)

Substituting this value of x 1 in Equation (3.11), we get

p x 2 = ( 2 θ 1 θ 1 2 ) p m 4 3 θ 1 2

p x 2 = ( 2 + θ 1 ) ( 1 θ 1 ) p m 4 3 θ 1 2 (3.12)

Now we need to find x 2 and p x 1 , for that substitute value of x 1 and p x 2 from (3.11) and (3.12) in Equation (3.5), which is

p x 1 = ( 1 θ 1 ) p m ( 1 θ 1 2 ) x 1 + θ 1 p x 2 (3.13)

Then we get

p x 1 = ( 1 θ 1 ) p m ( 1 θ 1 2 ) ( 2 θ 1 ) p m 4 3 θ 1 2 + θ 1 ( 2 + θ 1 ) ( 1 θ 1 ) p m 4 3 θ 1 2

p x 1 = [ ( 1 θ 1 ) ( 4 3 θ 1 2 ) ( 1 θ 1 2 ) ( 2 θ 1 ) + θ 1 ( 2 + θ 1 ) ( 1 θ 1 ) ] p m 4 3 θ 1 2

p x 1 = [ ( 1 θ 1 ) { ( 4 3 θ 1 2 ) ( 1 + θ 1 ) ( 2 θ 1 ) + θ 1 ( 2 + θ 1 ) } ] p m 4 3 θ 1 2

p x 1 = [ ( 1 θ 1 ) ( 2 + θ 1 θ 1 2 ) ] p m 4 3 θ 1 2

p x 1 = ( 1 θ 1 ) ( 1 + θ 1 ) ( 2 θ 1 ) p m 4 3 θ 1 2

p x 1 = ( 1 θ 1 2 ) ( 2 θ 1 ) p m 4 3 θ 1 2 (3.14)

Next for value of x 2 , use values of (3.12) and (3.13) in Equation (3.4), so that

x 2 = 1 1 θ 1 2 [ ( 1 θ 1 ) p m + θ 1 ( 1 θ 1 2 ) ( 2 θ 1 ) p m 4 3 θ 1 2 ( 2 + θ 1 ) ( 1 θ 1 ) p m 4 3 θ 1 2 ]

x 2 = 1 θ 1 1 θ 1 2 [ ( ( 4 3 θ 1 2 ) + θ 1 ( 1 + θ 1 ) ( 2 θ 1 ) ( 2 + θ 1 ) ) p m 4 3 θ 1 2 ]

x 2 = 1 1 + θ 1 ( 2 + θ 1 2 θ 1 2 θ 1 3 ) p m 4 3 θ 1 2

x 2 = 1 1 + θ 1 [ ( θ 1 + 1 ) ( 1 θ 1 ) ( 2 + θ 1 ) p m 4 3 θ 1 2 ]

(3.15)

So, CB competition Equations (3.11) and (3.14) give equilibrium output and Equations (3.12) and (3.13) give equilibrium price. Substitute these values in profit function to get CB profit

π x 1 C B = ( 2 θ 1 ) 2 ( 1 θ 1 ) 2 p m 2 ( 4 3 θ 1 2 ) 2

and

π x 2 C B = ( 2 + θ 1 ) 2 ( 1 θ 1 ) 2 p m 2 ( 4 3 θ 1 2 ) 2

of both the firms respectively. When we take the ratio of the output, prices and profit of both the firms, then observations are as follows:

x 1 x 2 = 2 θ 1 2 θ 1 θ 1 2 > 1 [ 0 < θ 1 < 1 ]

p x 1 p x 2 = 2 + θ 1 θ 1 2 2 + θ 1 < 1

and

π x 1 π x 2 = 4 3 θ 1 2 + θ 1 3 4 3 θ 1 2 θ 1 3 > 1

Similarly, in BC competition, the case is reversed only. In this case, firm 1 is price setter and takes price as variable considering output of the other is given and firm 2 is quantity setter, takes quantity as variable considering price of other as given. So, we need to just replace x 1 by x 2 and p x 1 by p x 2 in the above drawn results. Then observations are as follows:

x 1 x 2 = 2 θ 1 θ 1 2 2 θ 1 < 1

p x 1 p x 2 = 2 + θ 1 2 + θ 1 θ 1 2 > 1

π x 1 π x 2 = 4 3 θ 1 2 θ 1 3 4 3 θ 1 2 + θ 1 3 < 1

Above observations clearly indicate that in both CB and BC competition, out of two firms producing differentiated goods and following heterogeneous strategy, the quantity setter firm produces more output, have fewer prices and enjoys more profits.

4. Duopoly Model with Non-Linear Demand

Here we take an assumption that demand is iso-elastic [22]. Then inverse non-linear demand function is given by

p x 1 = 1 x 1 + θ 1 x 2

and

p x 2 = 1 θ 1 x 1 + x 2

x 1 p x 1 + θ 1 p x 1 x 2 = 1 (4.1)

and

θ 1 x 1 p x 2 + p x 2 x 2 = 1 (4.2)

Solve these equations for the output of firms x 1 and x 2 Then

x 1 = 1 1 θ 1 2 ( 1 p x 1 θ 1 p x 2 ) (4.3)

and

x 2 = 1 1 θ 1 2 ( θ 1 p x 1 1 p x 2 ) (4.4)

In CB competition with non-linear demand function, reaction functions will be obtained as in case of linear demand functions. We will get CB reaction functions for firm 1 and firm 2 as

θ 1 p x 2 = c 1 ( ( 1 θ 1 2 ) x 1 p x 2 + θ 1 ) 2 (4.5)

θ 1 x 1 p x 2 2 = c 2 (4.6)

Here reactions functions are function of two variables x 1 and p x 2 as mentioned above. But for sake of convenience, convert the reaction functions in variables x 1 and x 2 , and substitute the value of p x 2 in Equation (4.5), we get

θ 1 θ 1 x 1 + x 2 = c 1 ( ( 1 θ 1 2 ) x 1 θ 1 x 1 + x 2 + θ 1 ) 2

θ 1 ( θ 1 x 1 + x 2 ) = c 1 ( x 1 + θ 1 x 2 ) 2 (4.7)

Similarly, we get

θ 1 x 1 = c 2 ( θ 1 x 1 + x 2 ) 2 (4.8)

Dividing (4.7) by (4.8)

θ 1 + x 2 x 1 = c 1 c 2 ( 1 + θ 1 x 2 x 1 θ 1 + x 2 x 1 ) 2

Take y = x 2 x 1 and α = c 2 c 1 , Then

α ( θ 1 + y ) = ( 1 + θ 1 y θ 1 + y ) 2 (4.9)

Let the right hand side of Equation (4.9) be denoted by F ( y ) and left hand side be denoted by G C B ( y ) . Let the solution of Equation (4.9) be denoted by Y. So, intersection of F ( y ) and G C B ( y ) gives CB equilibrium.

Y = x 2 x 1 (4.10)

In order to express the value of CB output in terms of Y. Use (4.7) to get

θ 1 ( θ 1 x 1 + x 2 ) = c 1 ( x 1 + θ 1 x 2 ) 2

θ 1 x 1 ( θ 1 + x 2 x 1 ) = c 1 x 1 2 ( 1 + θ 1 x 2 x 1 ) 2

θ 1 x 1 ( θ 1 + Y ) = c 1 x 1 2 ( 1 + θ 1 Y ) 2

x 1 = θ 1 ( θ 1 + Y ) c 1 ( 1 + θ 1 Y ) 2

Also from (4.8)

θ 1 = c 2 x 1 ( θ 1 + x 2 x 1 ) 2

x 1 = θ 1 c 2 ( θ 1 + Y ) 2 (4.11)

Similarly

x 2 = Y θ 1 ( θ 1 + Y ) c 1 ( 1 + θ 1 Y ) 2 = Y θ 1 c 2 ( θ 1 + Y ) 2 (4.12)

Also express prices and profits of both the firms in terms of parameter Y so that it can be compared. For this substitute values of x 1 and x 2 in p x 1 and p x 2 to get

p x 1 = c 2 ( θ 1 + Y ) 2 θ 1 ( θ 1 Y + 1 )

p x 1 = 1 x 1 C B ( θ 1 Y + 1 ) (4.13)

Similarly

p x 2 = 1 x 1 C B ( θ 1 + Y ) (4.14)

Now, profit in CB equilibrium of firm 1 is

π x 1 = ( p x 1 c 1 ) x 1 C B

π x 1 = ( 1 ( 1 + θ 1 Y ) x 1 C B c 1 ) x 1 C B

π x 1 = 1 1 + θ 1 Y θ 1 ( θ 1 + Y ) ( 1 + θ 1 Y ) 2

π x 1 = 1 θ 1 2 ( 1 + θ 1 Y ) 2

In the similar way

π x 2 = Y 2 α 1 θ 1 2 ( θ 1 Y + 1 θ 1 + Y ) 2

Taking ratio of output, prices and profits of both the firms, we get

x 2 x 1 = Y , p x 2 p x 1 = θ 1 Y + 1 θ 1 + Y and π x 2 π x 1 = Y 2 ( θ 1 Y + 1 ) 2 1 θ 1 2 ( θ 1 + Y ) 2 (4.15)

From (4.9) and (4.10), it is clear that

G C B ( Y ) = F ( Y )

Now

θ 1 Y + 1 θ 1 + Y 1 or θ 1 Y + 1 θ 1 + Y 1

According as Y 1 or Y 1 , F ( 1 ) = 1 , and considering G C B ( 1 ) = 1 , we get a critical value of production cost ratio α . Let this value be denoted by α ¯ , then

α ¯ = 1 1 + θ 1 < 1 , 0 < θ 1 < 1

As mentioned above, If Y > 1 , θ 1 Y + 1 θ 1 + Y < 1 . So, from Equation (4.9), it is obtained that

α ( θ 1 + Y ) < 1

α < 1 θ 1 + Y < 1 θ 1 + 1 = α ¯

Similarly, for Y < 1 , θ 1 Y + 1 θ 1 + Y > 1 . Then, Equation (4.9) gives

α ( θ 1 + Y ) > 1

α > 1 θ 1 + Y > 1 θ 1 + 1 = α ¯

So, x 2 C B x 1 C B = Y , <1, =1 or >1 And p x 2 p x 1 = θ 1 Y + 1 θ 1 + Y 1 or θ 1 Y + 1 θ 1 + Y 1

According as α > α ¯ , = α ¯ or α < α ¯ .

This means that the parameter region { ( θ 1 , α ) : 0 < θ 1 < 1 , α > 0 } has two sub-regions, below and above the curve α = α ¯ . x 1 C B > x 2 C B and p x 1 C B < p x 2 C B for ( θ 1 , α ) in the region above the curve. x 1 C B < x 2 C B and p x 1 C B > p x 2 C B below the curve α = α ¯ . This can be interpreted that whichever firm produces more output sells at lower prices.

Bertrand Cournot Competitions

In BC competition, firm 1 is the price setter and the second is quantity setter. Following the above stated procedure, the reaction functions are

θ 1 x 2 p x 1 2 = c 1 (4.16)

θ 1 p x 1 = c 2 ( θ 1 ( 1 θ 1 2 ) x 2 p x 1 ) 2 (4.17)

The reaction functions given in above equations are defined in ( p x 1 , x 2 ) space. BC equilibrium will be converted in quantity space ( x 1 , x 2 ) by substituting values of p x 1 in these equations. Equation (4.16) becomes

θ 1 x 2 = c 1 ( x 1 + θ 1 x 2 ) 2 (4.18)

Similarly, Equation (4.17) becomes

θ 1 ( x 1 + θ 1 x 2 ) = c 2 [ ( 1 θ 1 2 ) x 2 + θ 1 ( x 1 + θ 1 x 2 ) ] 2

i.e.

θ 1 ( x 1 + θ 1 x 2 ) = c 2 [ x 2 + θ 1 x 1 ] 2 (4.19)

Equations (4.18) and (4.19) are defined in ( x 1 , x 2 ) space. Dividing (4.18) and (4.19) gives

θ 1 ( x 1 + θ 1 x 2 ) θ 1 x 2 = c 2 c 1 ( x 2 + θ 1 x 1 x 1 + θ 1 x 2 ) 2

Taking α = c 2 c 1 , y = x 2 x 1 , above equation becomes,

α y 1 + θ 1 y = ( θ 1 y + 1 θ 1 + y ) 2 (4.20)

Right hand side of Equation (4.20) and Equation (4.9) is the same.

As above, denote right hand side by F ( y ) and left hand side by G B C ( y ) . Solution of Equation (4.20) will be given by intersection of these two functions.

This solution is BC equilibrium.

Since G B C ( y ) is monotonically increasing and l i m y G B C ( y ) = α θ 1 . So, G B C ( y ) is bounded above. Also, l i m y F ( y ) = θ 1 2 .

Here, lim y G B C ( y ) > lim y F ( y ) .

This is equivalent to α > θ 1 3 .

So, here conjecture is α > θ 1 3 .

Let roots of Equation (4.20) be denoted by Z, which is a function of θ 1 and α .

Z = x 2 B C x 1 B C and α Z 1 + θ 1 Z = ( 1 + θ 1 Z θ 1 + Z ) 2 (4.21)

Substituting x 1 B C and x 2 B C = Z x 1 B C in Equations (4.18) and (4.19), in order to get explicit form of BC output in terms of parameters. Then

x 1 B C = θ 1 Z c 1 ( 1 + θ 1 Z ) 2 = θ 1 ( 1 + θ 1 Z ) c 2 ( θ 1 + Z ) 2 > 0 (4.22)

and for finding value of x 2 B C , take x 1 B C = x 2 B C Z in Equations (4.18) and (4.19).

x 2 B C = θ 1 Z 2 c 1 ( 1 + θ 1 Z ) 2 = θ 1 Z ( 1 + θ 1 Z ) c 2 ( θ 1 + Z ) 2 > 0 (4.23)

Substituting values of x 1 B C and x 2 B C from Equations (4.22) and (4.23) in equations

p x 1 = 1 x 1 + θ 1 x 2 and p x 2 = 1 x 2 + θ 1 x 1

BC prices are

p x 1 B C = 1 ( 1 + θ 1 Z ) x 1 B C and p x 2 B C = 1 ( Z + θ 1 ) x 1 B C

Their ratios are

p x 2 B C p x 1 B C = 1 + θ 1 Z θ 1 + Z (4.24)

As mentioned above, G B C ( 1 ) = 1 , this will give a critical value of production cost ratio, denote it by α ¯ . From expression (4.20), using G B C ( 1 ) = 1 , it is obtained that α ¯ = 1 + θ 1 .

If Z > 1

1 + θ 1 Z Z + θ 1 [ 0 < θ 1 < 1 ]

i.e. 1 + θ 1 Z Z + θ 1 1

From Equation (4.21), it is clear that

α Z 1 + θ 1 Z < 1

i.e. α < 1 + θ 1 Z Z = 1 Z + θ 1

i.e. α < 1 + θ 1 [ 1 Z < 1 ]

i.e. α < α ¯

Similarly, for Z < 1 , 1 + θ 1 Z Z + θ 1 1 , α > α ¯ .

This means output of firm 1 is more than that of firm 2, and its prices are lesser above the critical line α ¯ = 1 + θ 1 . But in the region below the critical line, firm 2 produces more output than the firm 1 and set lower prices.

When repeating the above procedure, we reach the conclusion that efficient firm produces more output and sells at lower price. Here efficient means production cost is less.

5. Conclusions

In a duopoly market system when both firms choose heterogeneous strategies i.e. one of the firms chooses quantity strategies and the other chooses price strategies, it is observed that when production costs are homogeneous, then quantity setter firms produce more output, face lower prices, and make larger profits than price setter firm. So, the quantity strategy is more profitable. When strategies and production costs are heterogeneous, the efficiency of the firms is the determining factor to decide which firm will produce more and sell at a lower price.

This paper studies the static aspects of the non-linear heterogeneous duopoly model. There is a future scope for investigating the dynamical aspects with numerical simulation.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest regarding the publication of this paper.

References

[1] Agiza, H.N. (1998) Explicit Stability Zones for Cournot Games with 3 and 4 Competitors. Chaos Solitons and Fractals, 9, 1955-1966.
https://doi.org/10.1016/S0960-0779(98)00006-X
[2] Arrow, K.J. and Hahn, F. (1971) General Competitive Analysis. Holden-Day, San Francisco.
[3] Schumpeter, J. (1954) History of Economic Analysis. Oxford University Press, New York.
[4] Baumol, W.J. (1971) Economic Theory and Operations Analysis. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs.
[5] Robinson, J. (1933) The Economics of the Imperfect Competition. Macmilllan Publishers, London.
[6] Bischi, G.-I. and Kopel, M. (2001) Equilibrium Selection in a Nonlinear Duopoly Game with Adaptive Expectations. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 46, 73-100. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-2681(01)00188-3
[7] Bischi, G.I. and Naimzada, A.(1999) Global Analysis of a Dynamic Duopoly Game with Bounded Rationality. Annals of the International Society of Dynamic Games, 5, 362-385. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4612-1336-9_20
[8] Edgeworth, F.Y. (1925) Papers Relating to Political Economy. 1st Edition, Macmilllan Publishers, London.
[9] Matsumoto, A. (2006) Controlling the Cournot-Nash Chaos. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 128, 379-392.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10957-006-9021-z
[10] Neumann, J.V. and Morgenstern, O. (1944) Theory of Games and Economic Behaviour. Princeton University Press, Princeton.
[11] Bischi, G., Chiarella, C., Kopel, M. and Szidarovszky, F. (2010) Nonlinear Oligopolies: Stability and Bifurcations. Springer, London.
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-02106-0
[12] Matsumoto, A. and Onozaki, T. (2005) Linear Differentiated Duopoly with Heterogeneous Production Costs in Heterogeneous Competition. Mimeo, New York.
[13] Hildenbrand, W. and Kirman, A.P. (1976) Introduction to Equilibrium Analysis. Elsevier, North-Holland.
[14] Ahmed, E. and Agiza, H.N. (1998) Dynamics of a Cournot Game with n-Competitors. Chaos, Solitons and Fractals, 9, 1513-1517.
https://doi.org/10.1016/S0960-0779(97)00131-8
[15] Singh, N. and Vives, X. (1984) Price and Quantity Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly Rand. Journal of Economics, 15, 546-554. https://doi.org/10.2307/2555525
[16] Bonanno, G. and Haworth, B. (1998) Intensity of Competition and the Choice between Product and Process Innovation. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 16, 495-510. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-7187(97)00003-9
[17] Chemberlin, E.H. (1932) The Theory of Monopolistic Competition. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
[18] Lu, J. (2017) Study of Informative Advertising Competition Model in Duopolistic Market with Relative Profit Object. Journal of Service Science and Management, 10, 105-111. https://doi.org/10.4236/jssm.2017.102009
[19] Lgbudu, S. and Fadare, D. (2021) Parametric Study on the Effect of Aspect Ratio of Selected Cooling Hole Geometries on the Mechanical Response of an Automobile Aluminium Alloy Wheel. Open Journal of Applied Sciences, 11, 41-57.
https://doi.org/10.4236/ojapps.2021.111004
[20] Schneider, E. (1960) Hans von Mangoldt on Price Theory: A Contribution to the History of Mathematical Economics. Journal of the Econometric Society, 28, 380-392. https://doi.org/10.2307/1907728
[21] Rand, D. (1978) Exotic Phenomena in Games and Duopoly Models. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 5, 173-184. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-4068(78)90022-8
[22] Puu, T. (1996, 1998) The Chaotic Duopolists Revisited. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 33, 385-394. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-2681(97)00064-4

Copyright © 2024 by authors and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

Creative Commons License

This work and the related PDF file are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.