1. Introduction
This study proposes a new monetary growth model involving price stickiness and endogenous R & D. Short-run macroeconomic models usually consider price stickiness, as in new Keynesian models. In this study, we introduce nominal wage stickiness into a long-run growth model based on R & D and investigate how money growth affects long-run output, employment, and economic growth.
We base the dynamics of our model on the new Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC), under which money is not super neutral, even in the long run1. [2] [3] proposed the Dynamic General Equilibrium (DGE) model with the NKPC and technological change, in which money is not super neutral in the long run and the long-run output gap exists when the monetary growth rate is below that of technological change. However, their analyses assumed exogenous technological change. This study proposes a DGE model based on the work of [2] with endogenous technological change rather than exogenous growth by introducing explicit R & D activities.
We focus on the steady-state economic growth and employment. For sufficiently high money growth rates, there is a unique balanced growth path, and the economy exhibits sustained growth based on sustained R & D. Faster money growth causes greater employment and faster economic growth along the balanced growth path. Furthermore, under some parameter restrictions, there is no balanced growth path for low money growth rates, and the economy is trapped in a steady state without long-run growth. These results suggest that money growth may be an important factor for long- run economic growth. That is, financial authorities are required to maintain high money growth rates to achieve sustained and faster economic growth.
Most of the preceding theoretical studies on money and endogenous growth have concluded that a higher money growth is associated with a lower rate of long-run growth, which is contrary to the conclusion of this study. See for example [4] - [8] . In contrast, [9] [10] have demonstrated the positive relationship between a monetary expan- sion and long-run growth using the infinitely lived overlapping-generation models. Some studies such as [11] - [13] proposed endogenous growth models that introduced nominal rigidities. [11] investigated how the volatility of monetary policy affects output growth under price and wage stickiness. [12] studied optimal monetary policy by using an endogenous growth model with a sticky price due to Calvo pricing, and showed that the optimal steady-state inflation rate is zero. [13] proposed an endo- genous growth model with sticky wage due to staggered Taylor wage contracts, and found a nonlinear relationship between money growth and long-run economic growth. In these studies, sustained growth becomes endogenous through learning-by-doing or simple externality, which differ from our study focusing on R & D as the engine of economic growth2. This study proposes a new channel attributed to nominal rigidities and endogenous R & D through which money growth influences the long-run economic growth.
Some empirical studies argued that inflation has a negative impact on economic growth ( [15] - [17] ). However, [18] [19] pointed out that the negative correlation between inflation and growth is not robust. [20] concluded that growth and inflation are negatively related only in the extremely high inflationary economy. Furthermore, a number of empirical studies showed positive relationships between inflation (or money growth) and economic growth for advanced countries. See for example [21] - [26] 3. Our study provides a theoretical explanation for these empirical results.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 sets up the model used in our theoretical investigation. Section 3 derives the law of motion and the steady state, which characterize the equilibrium path of the economy. It also investigates the existence and the uniqueness of the steady state. Section 4 concludes the paper.
2. Model
We consider the continuous-time version of the dynamic model based on [2] [27] . Let us assume an economy populated by many infinitely-lived households under monopolistic competition in the labor market, and there are rigidities of nominal wage. There is a single final good, which is produced using intermediate goods and supplied competitively. A new variety of intermediate goods is invented by allocating labor for R & D activities, and inventors enjoy infinitely-lived monopoly power. The available inter-mediate goods are produced by multiple intermediate firms using labor. Finally, we use the simple monetary policy rule under which financial authorities expand money supply at a constant rate.
2.1. Employment Agency
The manufacturing and R & D sectors regard each household's labor as an imperfect substitute for any other household's labor. To simplify the analysis, we assume that an employment agency combines differentiated labor forces into a composite labor force
according to the Dixit-Stiglitz function,
, and supplies com-
posite labor to the intermediate goods and the R & D sectors.
denotes differentiated labor supplied by household
, and l is the composite labor force. The number of households is normalized to 1.
is the elasticity of substitution between each pair of differentiated labor inputs.
Cost minimization of the employment agency yields the demand functions for dif- ferentiated labor j,
, where
denotes the nominal wage rate of labor force j, and W denotes the nominal wage rate of the composite labor force, which is given by
.
2.2. Final Goods Sector
We assume that perfect competition prevails in the final goods market. The final goods firm produces the quantity y according to the Dixit-Stiglitz function,

where
is the quantity of intermediate goods indexed by
, and
represents the elasticity of substitution between every pair of intermediate goods. N is the number of available intermediate goods and represents the technology level of the economy. The final goods firm faces diminishing returns with each intermediate good; therefore, greater values of N imply higher productivity.
Cost minimization by the final-goods producing firm yields the following demand functions for intermediate goods
:
(1)
where
is the price of intermediate goods i, and p is the price of the final good or the price level, which is given by
.
2.3. Intermediate Goods Sector
Each intermediate good is produced using one unit of composite labor; thus, marginal cost is equal to the nominal wage level, W. Because patents have an infinite life, all intermediate goods are supplied monopolistically. Maximization of the monopoly pro- fit,
, subject to the demand function (1) yields
(2)
where
represents the amount of composite labor allocated to the production of the intermediate goods. All intermediate goods enter symmetrically into production of the final good. Moreover, the maximized monopoly profit is
(3)
From (2), the market equilibrium levels of output, y, and the price of the final good, p, are obtained as
(4)
(5)
We can rewrite (5) as ![]()
2.4. R & D Sector
The number of intermediate goods, N, expands according to the following equation:
(6)
where
is the parameter that reflects the productivity of R & D.
represents the amount of composite labor allocated to R & D, and clearing the labor market requires
.
In equilibrium, the following free-entry condition must be satisfied:
(7)
The right-hand side is the nominal unit cost of R & D. V represents the value of the patent, which is given by the discounted stream of the monopoly profit:
![]()
where R is the nominal interest rate. Differentiating both sides with respect to time, t, yields the following no-arbitrage condition:
(8)
2.5. Households
Household j possesses nominal money balances,
, and share of the monopoly firms,
. The share
yields returns at rate R. Thus, the budget constraint of household
is given by
![]()
where
is the nominal assets of household j,
is labor supplied elastically by household j, and
is consumption of household j.
is nominal transfer income from the financial authorities in a lump-sum fashion. The final goods market clears
when
. We can rewrite the budget constraint in real terms as
![]()
where
is the real interest rate,
is the inflation rate,
is real money balances, and
is the stock of assets in real terms.
Household j obtains utility from consumption,
, and real money balances,
, and it encounters disutility from the labor supply,
, and wage negotiations. Thus, the instantaneous utility function of household j is
![]()
where
is the elasticity of the marginal disutility of the labor supply.
denotes the scale of the nominal wage adjustment cost from wage negotiations and
4. If
, the nominal wage is flexible; however, if
, the nominal wage is sticky.
and
denote the utility weights on real money balances and labor supply, respectively.
Summarizing the above, household j faces the following dynamical optimization problem:
![]()
where
is the subjective discount rate. Since all households behave symme- trically according to the same equations,
,
,
,
, and
hold. When
, the solution to the optimization problem above is cha- racterized by the Euler equation and the wage version of the NKPC, as follows:
(9)
where
is real money balances for the entire economy. The transversality condition for the households is given by
.
On the other hand, when
the following equation holds instead of the NKPC (9):
(10)
2.6. Money Growth
Financial authorities are assumed to change money supply, M, at a constant rate
. That is, the financial policy rule is given by
. Therefore,
holds. All seignorage is transfered to households; that is,
.
3. Steady State
When the nominal wage is sticky (
), and the positive composite labor is allocated to R & D at any time (
) the equilibrium path is characterized by the transversality condition and the following differential equations:
(11)
(12)
(13)
where
and
(14)
When R,
, and
are given, we obtain the
,
, and
as follows:
(15)
(16)
(17)
and
were defined as
and
.
3.1. Balanced Growth Path
If the law of motion (11) through (13) has fixed points, they are derived as follows:
![]()
where
is the increasing function of
defined as
.
is determined by the following wage version of the long-run Phillips curve:
(18)
The steady-state values of
and
are
(19)
However, to guarantee that
is positive,
must be greater than
.
If it is the case that
, at this fixed point y and N grow at constant rates. That is, the economy achieves balanced growth. We shall define this steady state as the balanced growth path (BGP). From (4) and (6), the balanced-growth rate of output is derived as
. From (17), the inflation rate along the BGP is given by the difference between the money growth rate and the long-run growth rate; that is,
.
3.2. Natural Employment Level
We refer to the output and employment level in the flexible-price economy (i.e., when
) as the natural output level and the natural employment level. The employment gap is the difference between the actual and natural employment levels. In the flexible-price economy, the employment level, l, is characterized by (10) instead of
NKPC (9). Then, substituting (4), (19),
and
into (10), we obtain the natural employment level along the BGP,
, as the root of the following implicit function:
![]()
3.3. Existence and Uniqueness of the Balanced Growth Path
3.3.1. Case of Non-Negative Money Growth
When
(
) belongs to
, the long-run Phillips curve (18) is upward sloping on a
-plane as shown in Figure 1. Note that the horizontal axis measures the employment level instead of the unemployment rate or the employment gap since we focus on the employment level rather than the unemployment rate in this study. Therefore, the usual Phillips curve is flipped backward in Figure 1.
![]()
Figure 1. The long-run Phillips curve at the BGP (for
).
When
is given, the BGP level of employment,
, is uniquely determined according to the long-run Phillips curve. However, for a small value of
, the root of the equation,
, is smaller than
; it is inappropriate for the BGP value. This threshold is given by
![]()
These results may be summarized as follows:
Proposition 1. Let
. If and only if
, a unique BGP,
, exists. On the other hand, if
, there is no BGP.
When the R & D sector is sufficiently productive and the parameters satisfy
![]()
holds; thus,
always holds. In this case, when the financial authorities apply a monetary policy with
,
holds and the employment gap caused by nominal wage stickiness is eliminated.
If
, the existence of the BGP requires that the money growth rate,
, is sufficiently high. When
is small and the BGP does not exist, there is only the no- growth steady state mentioned below.
3.3.2. Case Allowing Money Contraction
Some algebra shows that
,
and
. Therefore, when we allow a negative value of
,
is convex and a unimodal form through the origin as shown in Figure 2. However,
is bounded by
to guarantee that the BGP value of the nominal interest rate,
, is positive.
When the parameters satisfy
![]()
[see Figure 2(a) and Figure 2(b)]. In contrast, for
,
holds [see Figure 2(c) and Figure 2(d)]. Moreover, if the parameters satisfy
![]()
is greater than
[see Figure 2(a) and Figure 2(c)]. For
,
holds [see Figure 2(b) and Figure 2(d)]5. To sum up these findings, we can see four cases as shown in Figures 2(a)-(d)6.
At first, in the cases of Figure 2(b) and Figure 2(d),
has a unique root such that
for all
. That is, a unique BGP exists for all possible money growth rates.
In the case of Figure 2(a),
is again a necessary and sufficient condition for the existence of a unique BGP. That is, sufficiently high rates of money growth are required to achieve sustained economic growth.
The following proposition summarizes the above properties.
Proposition 2.
1. If the parameters satisfy
, a unique BGP,
, exists for all
.
2. Let the parameters satisfy
. If and only if
, a unique BGP,
, exists. In contrast, if
, there is no BGP.
On the other hand, in the case of Figure 2(c), it is possible that
has dual roots,
and
, which belong to
under a contractionary monetary policy7. To put it more precisely, we can state the following proposition.
Proposition 3. Let
hold. For
, a unique BGP,
, exists. For
close enough to
, dual BGPs,
and
, exist.
Letting
, we obtain
. Therefore, when the money growth rate,
, is smaller than
and belongs to the neighborhood of
, BGPs with a high and low growth rate coexist. Our model has no mechanism to choose between them. That is, global indeterminacy arises. The behavior of the economy is determined by agents’ expectations. If the minimum value of
is greater than
, by de- creasing
toward
, a saddle-node bifurcation will occur and the BGPs will vanish.
The arguments of Propositions 1 through 3 are summarized in Table 1 for the case of
.
3.4. Money Growth, Inflation, and Economic Growth
Let a unique BGP exist. Then, we obtain the following proposition.
Proposition 4. Let
hold and a unique BGP exists. In response to a permanent increase in the money growth rate,
, the economy experiences greater employment and faster economic growth along the unique BGP.
This proposition can be proved as follows. As shown in Figure 1 and Figure 2, when a unique BGP exists,
lies on the upward-slope of the long-run Phillips curve. There-
![]()
Table 1. The existence and uniqueness of BGP (
).
Note: “―” shows that no such combinations of parameters exist because
.
fore, an increase in
raises the BGP level of employment,
. Since
and
, an increase in
raises labor allocated to each sector8. As a result, since
, the greater value of
raises
. That is, economic growth accelerates with money growth9.
Furthermore, consider the following two facts. First, the growth acceleration effect of money growth is attributed purely to nominal wage stickiness. A small value of
diminishes the impact of money growth on employment and economic growth. In a flexible-price economy, a change in the money growth rate has no effect on employ- ment and economic growth. That is, money is super neutral10. Second, even if financial authorities add 1% to the money growth rate, the rise in the long-run inflation rate is smaller than 1% because of the rise in the long-run growth rate
. That is, the impact of money growth on the long-run inflation rate is weakened by endogenizing growth. Moreover, for high productivity R & D, which is captured by large values of
, the inflation rate might even decrease.
As for dual BGPs, we can prove the following proposition in a similar way to that of Proposition 4.
Proposition 5. Let dual BGPs exist. At the BGP with lower employment level, an increase in the money growth rate raises employment and the balanced-growth rate. Whereas, at the BGP with a higher employment level, an increase in the money growth rate depresses employment and the balanced-growth rate.
3.5. No-Growth Steady State
There exists a different steady state from the BGP at which no labor is allocated to R & D and long-run growth never occurs. We refer to such a steady state as the no-growth steady state. At the no-growth steady state, since the free-entry condition (7) does not hold with an equality, (14), (15), and (16) are not fulfilled, and
and
hold instead of them.
The value of each variable at this steady state is derived as follows:11
![]()
If and only if
, the no-growth steady state,
, exists12. When
and there is no BGP, the no-growth steady state,
, is a unique steady state of the economy. If two BGPs exist as shown in Proposition 3, there are three steady states in all, and global indeterminacy arises among them.
4. Conclusions
This study developed a R & D-based endogenous growth model by introducing money growth and a price adjustment process. This study assumed that nominal wage is adjusted stickily because of adjustment cost and derived the new Keynesian Phillips curve, under which money is not super neutral even in the long-run.
When the money growth rate is sufficiently high, the economy has a unique balanced growth path, and can sustain long-run positive growth based on sustained R & D. Fur- thermore, faster money growth brings greater employment and faster economic growth along a unique balanced growth path. In contrast, under some parameter restrictions, when the money growth rate is sufficiently low, there is no balanced growth path, and the economy is trapped in a no-growth steady state. These results suggest that money growth may be an important factor for long-run economic growth.
To highlight the effect of nominal wage stickiness, this study adopted the money-in- utility-function approach, under which money is supernatural in a flexible-price eco- nomy. One interesting extension would be to analyze a model with another specifi- cation for money demand, for example cash-in-advance approach. In such case, the super neutrality of money may not hold even in a flexible-price economy, and the growth acceleration effect which is argued in this study might be weakened or strengthened. Such topic will be the subject of future research.
Acknowledgements
We thank the Editor and the referee for their comments. This paper is a part of the outcome of research performed under a Waseda University Grant for Special Research Projects (Project number: 2015B-014).