Interactive Fuzzy Approaches for Solving Multiobjective Two-Person Zero-Sum Games ()
Received 20 January 2016; accepted 15 March 2016; published 18 March 2016

1. Introduction
In this paper, we propose interactive algorithms for multiobjectve two-person zero-sum games with vector payoffs and vector fuzzy payoffs under the assumption that each player has fuzzy goals for his/her multiple expected payoffs.
Shapley [1] first defined a Pareto equilibrium solution concept for two-person zero-sum games with vector payoffs, and proved the existence of a Pareto equilibrium solution by utilizing the weighting method for multiobjective optimization. Zeleny [2] formulated a two-person zero-sum game with vector payoffs as a single objective optimization problem to obtain the minimax solution. Cook [3] also formulated a two-person zero-sum game with vector payoffs as a goal programming problem, in which each player sets goals for multiple expected payoffs and the distances between them are minimized. It was shown that such a goal progamming problem is reduced to a linear programming problem. Moreover, Ghose and Prasad [4] proposed a solution concept incor- porating not only the concept of Pareto optimality but also that of security levels. The concept of security levels is inherent in the definition of maximin solutions in two-person zero-sum games. Sakawa and Nishizaki [5] proposed a fuzzy approach for two-person zero-sum games with vector payoffs to obtain maximin solutions which are defined from the viewpoint of maximization of the degree of minimal goal attainment [6] [7] . They showed that such a problem is reduced to a linear programming problem.
On the other hand, Campos [8] first formulated two-person zero-sum games with fuzzy payoffs as fuzzy linear programming problems to obtain the maximin solutions. Li [9] [10] also formulated special types of two- person zero-sum games with fuzzy payoffs which are represented by triangular fuzzy numbers as three-objective linear programming problems, and proposed the corresponding computation method. Bector et al. [11] , Bector and Chandra [12] , and Vijay et al. [13] [14] proposed computational methods for solving not only two-person zero-sum games with fuzzy payoffs but also two-person nonzero-sum games with fuzzy payoffs, which are based on the duality of mathematical programming techniques. Maeda [15] introduced an order relationship between fuzzy numbers with respect to two-person zero-sum games with fuzzy payoffs, and proposed a solution concept.
As a natural extension to multiobjective programming problems, Nishizaki and Sakawa [16] - [18] focused on two-person zero-sum games with vector payoffs. By introducing the fuzzy goals, they formulated two-person zero-sum games with vector payoffs as a linear programming problem to obtain maximin solutions. They also investigated the equilibrium solutions in two-person non-zero-sum games with fuzzy goals and vector fuzzy payoffs. However, to deal with such games as linear programming problems, they assumed that fuzzy goals for each player are defined as linear membership functions, each element of fuzzy payoffs is also defined as a linear type fuzzy number, and each player adopts the fuzzy decision [7] [19] to integrate vector payoff or vector fuzzy payoffs. Therefore, the proposed methods cannot be applied if each player adopts fuzzy goals whose member- ship functions are nonlinear, each element of fuzzy payoffs is defined as a nonlinear type fuzzy number, or player does not adopt the fuzzy decision to integrate vector payoff or vector fuzzy payoffs.
In such situations, in this paper, we focus on two-person zero-sum games with vector fuzzy payoffs under the assumption that a player has fuzzy goals for the expected payoffs which are defined as nonlinear membership functions. In Section 2, introducing the pessimistic Pareto optimal solution concept by assuming that a player supposes the opponent adopts the most disadvantage strategy for the self, we translate two-person zero-sum games with vector payoffs into the corresponding multiobjective programming problems. We propose an inter- active algorithm based on the bisection method and linear programming techniques to obtain a pessimistic com- promise solution from among the set of all pessimistic Pareto optimal solutions. In Section 3, we also consider multiobjectve two-person zero-sum games with vector fuzzy payoffs, and propose an extended interactive algo- rithm to obtain a pessimistic compromise solution from among the pessimistic Pareto optimal solution set on the basis of the possibility measure [20] . In Section 4, as an application of our method, we consider a multi-variety vegetable shipment planning problem, which is formulated as a two-person zero-sum game with vector payoffs, and show the efficiency of the proposed algorithm.
2. Two-Person Zero-Sum Games with Vector Payoffs
We consider two-person zero-sum games with multiple payoffs which are defined by
matrices
. For each
-element
of the payoff matrices
,
, a row
is interpreted as a pure strategy of Player 1 and a column
is also a pure strategy of Player 2. When Player 1 chooses a pure strategy i and Player 2 chooses a pure strategy j, Players 1 and 2 receive K-dimensional payoff vectors
and
, respectively. Let
be a mixed strategy for Player 1 and let
be a mixed strategy for Player 2.
In this section, we assume that each player has fuzzy goals for his/her expected payoffs
, where
and
are mixed strategies specified by two players.
Assumption 1. Let
be the set of Player 1’s payoffs. Then, Player 1’s fuzzy goal
for the k-th payoff is a fuzzy set defined on the set
characterized by the following strictly increasing and continuous membership functions:
![]()
Similarly, the nonlinear membership functions
of Player 2's fuzzy goals are defined on
, and they are strictly increasing and continuous. ![]()
Then, we can formulate the following multiobjective programming problem for Player 1 under the assumption that Player 1 supposes Player 2 adopts the most disadvantage strategy for the self.
(1)
To deal with the multiobjective minimax problem (1), the following Pareto optimal solution concept can be defined.
Definition 1.
is said to be a Player 1’s pessimistic Pareto optimal solution to (1) if and only if there does not exist another
such that
![]()
with strict inequality holding for at least one k. ![]()
We assume that Player 1 can find a pessimistic compromise solution from among the pessimistic Pareto optimal solution set. It should be noted here that a pessimistic compromise solution concept is different from a satisfactory solution concept employed in usual multiobjective programming problems. A pessimistic com- promise solution can be interpreted as a most better solution among the pessimistic Pareto optimal solution set in his/her preference.
For generating a candidate of a pessimistic compromise solution, Player 1 is asked to specify the reference membership values [19] . Once the reference membership values
are specified, the corres- ponding pessimistic Pareto optimal solution is obtained by solving the minmax problem
(2)
By introducing auxiliary variable
, the problem (2) can be equivalently transformed into the nonlinear programming problem
(3)
Since the inverse functions
always exist because of Assumption 1, the constraints of (3) is transformed into the following equivalent inequalities:
(4)
As a result, the problem (3) is expressed as the following problem:
(5)
It should be noted here that the problem (5) can be easily solved by combined use of the bisection method and the first-phase of the two-phase simplex method of linear programming.
The relationship between the optimal solution
of the problem (5) and pessimistic Pareto optimal solutions can be characterized by the following theorem.
Theorem 1.
(i) If
is a unique optimal solution of (5), then
is a pessimistic Pareto optimal solution to (1).
(ii) If
is a pessimistic Pareto optimal solution to (1), then
is an optimal solution of (5) for some reference membership values
. ![]()
Proof:
(i) Since
is an optimal solution to (5), the following inequalities hold.
![]()
Assume that
is not a pessimistic Pareto optimal solution to (1). Then, there exists
such that
![]()
with strict inequality holding for at least one
. From Assumption 1, it holds that
![]()
This contradicts the fact that
is a unique optimal solution to (5).
(ii) Assume that
is not an optimal solution to (5) for any reference membership values
, which satisfy the inequalities
![]()
Then, there exists some
such that
![]()
From Assumption 1 and the fact that
, the following relation holds.
![]()
This contradict that the fact that
,
is a pessimistic Pareto optimal solution to (1). ![]()
Unfortunately, from Theorem 1, it is not guaranteed that the optimal solution
of (5) is pessimistic Pareto optimal, if
is not unique. In order to guarantee the pessimistic Pareto optimality, we assume that the following K constraints of (5) are active at the optimal solution, i.e.,
(6)
simultaneously hold. For the optimal solution
of (5), where the active conditions (6) are satisfied, we solve the following pessimistic Pareto optimality test problem:
Test problem 1:
(7)
Theorem 2. For the optimal solution
of Test problem 1 (7), if
, then
is a pessimistic Pareto optimal solution. ![]()
Now, from the above discussions, we can present an interactive algorithm for deriving a pessimistic compromise solution from among the pessimistic Pareto optimal solution set.
Interactive algorithm 1:
Step 1: Player 1 sets his/her membership functions
for the expected payoffs, which satisfy Assumption 1.
Step 2: Set the initial reference membership values as
.
Step 3: Solve the problem (5) by combined use of the bisection method and the first-phase of the two-phase simplex method of linear programming. For an optimal solution
, the corresponding Test problem 1 (7) is solved.
Step 4: If Player 1 agrees to the current pessimistic Pareto optimal solution, then stop. Otherwise, Player 1 updates his/her reference membership values
, and return to Step 3.
3. Two-Person Zero-Sum Games with Vector Fuzzy Payoffs
In this section, we consider two-person zero-sum games with vector fuzzy payoffs which are defined by
matrices
, whose
-element
is an LR fuzzy number [20] , and the corresponding membership function is defined as
![]()
where the function
is a real-valued continuous function from
to
, and
is a strictly decreasing continuous function satisfying
. Also, the function
satisfies the same conditions.
is the mean value,
and
are called the left and right spreads, respectively [20] . Similar to the previous section, let
be a mixed strategy for Player 1 and let
be a mixed strategy for Player 2. Then, according to operations of fuzzy numbers based on the extension principle [20] , the k-th fuzzy expected payoff of Player 1 becomes an LR fuzzy number whose membership function is defined by
![]()
In this section, we assume that Player 1 has fuzzy goals for his/her fuzzy expected payoffs
, whose membership functions are defined as follows.
Assumption 2. Let
be the set of Player 1’s fuzzy payoffs. Then, Player 1’s fuzzy goal
for the k-th fuzzy payoff is a fuzzy set defined on the set
characterized by the following strictly increasing and continuous membership functions:
![]()
where
means an a-cut set for fuzzy sets [20] . Similarly, Player 2’s membership functions
are defined on
, which are strictly increasing and continuous. ![]()
Using the concept of the possibility measure [20] , we define the value of the membership function
as follows:
(8)
where
is a membership function of Player 1’s fuzzy goal for the k-th payoff. Then, we can formulate the following multiobjective programming problem for Player 1 under the assumption that Player 1 supposes Player 2 adopts the most disadvantage strategy for the self.
(9)
In order to deal with the multiobjective maximin problem (9), we introduce the pessimistic Pareto optimality concept.
Definition 2.
is said to be a Player 1’s pessimistic Pareto optimal solution to (9) if and only if there does not exist another
such that
(10)
with strict inequality holding for at least one k. ![]()
The constraints (10) are transformed into the following forms, where
means the j-th column vectors of
.
(11)
It should be noted here that the decision vector
disappeared in the constraints (11).
Similar to the previous section, we assume that Player 1 can find a pessimistic compromise solution from among the pessimistic Pareto optimal solution set.
For generating a candidate of a pessimistic compromise solution, Player 1 is asked to specify the reference membership values [19] . Once the reference membership values
are specified, the corres- ponding pessimistic Pareto optimal solution is obtained by solving the minmax problem
(12)
This problem can be equivalently transformed into the following form:
(13)
where
. Since not only the inverse functions
but also
and
always exist, the k-th constraint of (13) is transformed into the following.
![]()
![]()
![]()
![]()
![]()
![]()
From the above discussion, the problem (13) for Player 1 can be expressed as
(14)
It should be noted here that the problem (14) can be easily solved by combined use of the bisection method with respect to
and the first-phase of the two-phase simplex method of linear programming.
The relationship between the optimal solution
of (14) and pessimistic Pareto optimal solutions to (9) can be characterized by the following theorem.
Theorem 3.
(i) If
is a unique optimal solution of (14), then
is a pessimistic Pareto optimal solution to (9).
(ii) If
is a pessimistic Pareto optimal solution to (9), then there exists
,
such that
![]()
is an optimal solution of (14) for some reference membership values
.
Proof:
(i) Since
is an optimal solution to (14), the following inequalities hold for any
.
![]()
Since the constraints of (13) are equivalent to those of (14), the following relations hold.
![]()
Assume that
is not a pessimistic Pareto optimal solution to (9). Then, there exists
such that
![]()
with strict inequality holding for at least one k. Therefore, it holds that
![]()
This contradicts the fact that
is a unique optimal solution to (14).
(ii) Assume that
,
is not an optimal solution to (14) for any reference membership values
which satisfy
![]()
Then, there exists some
such that
![]()
. This means that there exists some
such that
![]()
Because of
, there exists
such that
![]()
This contradict that the fact that
,
is a pessimistic Pareto optimal solution to (9). ![]()
Unfortunately, from Theorem 3, it is not guaranteed that the optimal solution
of (14) is pessimistic Pareto optimal, if
is not unique. In order to guarantee the pessimistic Pareto optimality, we assume that the following K constraints of (14) are active at the optimal solution, i.e.,
(15)
simultaneously hold. For the optimal solution
of (14) which satisfies the active conditions (15), we solve the pessimistic Pareto optimality test problem defined as follows:
Test problem 2:
(16)
Theorem 4. For the optimal solution
of Test problem 2 (16), if
, then
is a pessimistic Pareto optimal solution. ![]()
Now, from the above discussions, we can present an interactive algorithm for deriving a pessimistic compromise solution from among the pessimistic Pareto optimal solution set to (9).
Interactive algorithm 2:
Step 1: Player 1 sets his/her membership functions
for the fuzzy expected payoffs, which satisfy Assumption 2.
Step 2: Set the initial reference membership values as
.
Step 3: For the reference membership values
, solve the problem (14) by combined use of the bisection method and the first-phase of the two-phase simplex method of linear programming. For the optimal solution
, the corresponding test problem (16) is solved.
Step 4: If Player 1 agrees to the current pessimistic Pareto optimal solution, then stop. Otherwise, Player 1 updates his/her reference membership values
, and return to Step 3.
4. An Application to Multi-Variety Vegetable Shipment Planning
In this section, we apply the proposed method to multi-variety vegetable shipment planning problems. We assume that a farmer (Player 1) must decide a ratio of the shipment amount between tomato and cucumber. Table 1 and Table 2 show price lists
and
(Japanease yen/kg) of tomato and cucumber in Nagoya Central Wholesale Market in Japan for each period (from January to December) from 2009 to 2013 [21] .
![]()
Table 1. A price list
of tomato in Nagoya Central Wholesale Market in Japan (yen/kg).
![]()
Table 2. A price list
of cucumber in Nagoya Central Wholesale Market in Japan (yen/kg).
We assume that some column of the price lists arises in the future (in other words, Nature (Player 2) selects some year between 2009 to 2013). We also assume that miscellaneous costs to cultivate vegetables with manure can be ignored. Utilizing the
-dimensional matrices
of the price lists of tomato and cucumber, we define
-dimensional profit matrices
as follows:
![]()
where
means a
-dimensional zero matrix. Then, we formulate such a shipment planning problem as a two-person zero-some matrix game [22] . Let
be a mixed strategy of Player 1 (the farmer), where
for tomato and
for cucumber. Also, let
be a mixed
strategy of Player 2 (Nature). For example, if
, it follows that Nature selects the j-th year,
. This model means that the farmer wishes to maximize its expected income taking into account the worst-cost scenario. At Step 1 of Interactive algorithm 1, suppose that Player 1 sets his/her membership functions for the expected profits
as follows:
![]()
![]()
According to Interactive algorithm 1, Player 1 updates his/her reference membership values to obtain a candidate of the pessimistic compromise solution from among the pessimistic Pareto optimal solution set. The interactive process with a hypothetical Player 1 is summarized in Table 3.
![]()
Table 3. An interactive process with a hypothetical Player 1.
5. Conclusion
In this paper, we propose interactive algorithms for multiobjectve two-person zero-sum games with vector payoffs and vector fuzzy payoffs under the assumption that each player has fuzzy goals for his/her multiple expected payoffs. In the proposed method, we translate multiobjective two-person zero-sum games with fuzzy goals into the corresponding multiobjective programming problems and introduce the pessimistic Pareto optimal solution concept. The player can adopt nonlinear membership functions for fuzzy goals, and he/she can be guaranteed to obtain multiple expected payoffs, which are better than a pessimistic Pareto optimal solution whatever the other player does.