Specifying the EKC: Downstream Dependence in Water Pollution

Abstract

The present study provides a utility maximizing theoretical framework motivating the EKC model. Theoretical parameters are linked directly to the typical empirical parameters of the reduced form empirical EKC model. Linking the theory to the typical empirically estimated parameters is relevant for devising policy and future EKC studies.

Share and Cite:

Thompson, A. (2014) Specifying the EKC: Downstream Dependence in Water Pollution. Theoretical Economics Letters, 4, 743-747. doi: 10.4236/tel.2014.49094.

1. Introduction

The environmental Kuznets curve (EKC) describes the relationship between income per capita and environmental degradation as an inverted U-shape. At initial stages of economic development and low income per capita, environmental degradation increases with income because increased production leads to pollution. Eventually, the environmental problems are redressed as demand for environmental quality increases with rising income.

Since the initial EKC study by [1] , a number empirical EKC studies have been published [2] - [9] . Theoretical EKC models that have been developed to help motivate the EKC have included infinitely-lived agent models ( [10] [11] ) and overlapping generation models ( [12] ). [13] develop the Green Solow Model, an extension of the Solow model including a resource constraint.

[14] approach the EKC from a consumer standpoint and assumes increasing returns to pollution abatement. These authors derive conditions for a turning point or the point at which pollution degradation is maximized. The present study provides a utility maximizing theoretical framework motivating the EKC model. Theoretical parameters are linked directly to the typical empirical parameters of the reduced form empirical EKC model. Linking theoretical parameters to the typical empirically estimated parameters is relevant for devising policy and future EKC studies.

2. Theory

Consider agent 1 in the upstream country (U) and agent 2 in the downstream country (D). The utility of agent 1 is a general function of their consumption and pollution,

(1)

and the downstream agent utility is a function of their consumption and pollution,

(2)

Utility is quasi-concave in C and P for upstream and downstream agents. Pollution in the upstream country is a function of consumption and environmental effort,

(3)

where and.

Pollution in the downstream country is a function of consumption and environmental effort in the downstream country, plus the fraction of upstream pollution that travels downstream,

(4)

where and.

Income is spent on consumption and environmental effort Prices of and are normalized to 1 in the income constraint

(5)

where.

In a specified utility function, agent maximizes

(6)

where is the constant marginal disutility of pollution assumed equal to one. Upstream utility

(7)

where is the marginal disutility of pollution assumed equal to one. Upstream pollution is a quadratic function of consumption and environmental effort in upstream and downstream countries,

(8)

Substituting the pollution function into the utility function utility. For notational convenience let and. To ensure that the reduced form utility function is concave, assume and which in turn require the parameter restrictions and.

The upstream agent chooses consumption and effort to maximize utility, subject to the budget constraint. The adding-up conditions on the solutions to this problem require the further parameter restriction that 1. Optimal consumption and effort levels in the upstream country are

(9)

(10)

In general or

(11)

Again represents marginal disutility of pollution in the downstream country, assumed equal to one.

Pollution in the downstream country is

(12)

where represents the fraction of upstream pollution that flows downstream. For simplicity, assume so that all upstream pollution flows downstream. Substituting (8) into (12) expresses downstream pollution as a function of upstream and downstream consumption and environmental effort,

(13)

The potential of diminishing returns to pollution with respect to consumption and environmental effort is preserved from the A&L model.

Substituting (13) into (11) the utility of the downstream citizen is a function of their own consumption and environmental effort as well as upstream consumption and environmental effort,

(14)

subject to the constraint on income,. As above, impose the parameter restrictions, , and let and.

Treating and as constants and solving for optimal consumption and environmental effort in the downstream country yields

(15)

(16)

Substituting (9), (10), (15), and (16) in the downstream pollution function

(17)

and combining like terms and simplifying yields

(18)

Equation (18) requires the further restriction and.

The estimated EKC model follows

(19)

where is BOD per capita, is upstream income, is downstream income, and are coefficients to be estimated.

Linking the theoretical model with the empirical model, the second order marginal effects of consumption and effort on utility for the upstream country and and downstream country and can be derived from the following:

(20)

(21)

(22)

(23)

Solving for in terms of, , and yields

(24)

The parameter is unknown. The parameter can take any positive value as long as. Let

. Once is solved, the following expression can solve for:

. (25)

The parameters and can be solved using and in a similar manner.

Although this model is somewhat restrictive, this appears to be the first attempt to link a theoretical model of an EKC with an empirical model. This is important because the underlying causes of an EKC are debated. Some EKC theorists believe citizens make “greener” consumption choices as they grow richer, while other theorists believe the EKC is a reflection of harsher environmental regulations in higher income countries. The EKC empirical estimates can derive underlying second order effects of consumption and effort on utility. Results may offer insight into how consumers value consumption and effort and where their income should be spent.

3. Conclusion

This paper investigates downstream dependence in an EKC for water pollution. The question this paper addresses is whether downstream pollution can be redressed with income growth in the upstream country. A theoretical model is developed that relates theoretical parameters directly with the typical empirically estimated parameters of the reduced form EKC model. Theoretical parameters for upstream and downstream county consumption and environmental effort are derived. Future EKC studies may benefit from employing the theoretical model proposed in this paper to help devise appropriate policy for various pollution indicators.

Acknowledgements

Special thanks to Jeff Peterson, John Crespi, and Henry Thompson for comments.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

[1] Grossman, G.M. and Krueger, A.B. (1991) Environmental Impacts of a North American Free Trade Agreement. NBER Working Paper 3914.
[2] Perman, R. and Stern, D.I. (2003) Evidence from Panel Unit Root and Cointegration Tests That the Environmental Kuznets Curve Does Not Exist. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 47, 325-347.
[3] Panayotou, T. (1993) Empirical Tests and Policy Analysis of Environmental Degradation at Different Stages of Economic Development. Working Paper WP238, Technology and Employment Programme, International Labour Office, Geneva.
[4] Panayotou, T. (1995) Environmental Degradation at Different Stages of Economic Development. In: Ahmed, I. and Doeleman, J.A., Eds., Beyond Rio: The Environmental Crisis and Sustainable Livelihoods in the Third World, ILO Studies Series, St. Martin’s Press, New York.
[5] Sigman, H. (2002) International Spillovers and Water Quality in Rivers: Do Countries Free Ride? American Economic Review, 92, 1152-1159. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/00028280260344687
[6] Helland, E. and Whitford, A.B. (2003) Pollution Incidence and Political Jurisdiction: Evidence from the TRI. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 46, 403-424.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0095-0696(03)00033-0
[7] Maddison, D. (2006) Environmental Kuznets Curves: A Spatial Econometric Approach. Journal of Environment and Economics Resources, 51, 218-230.
[8] Paudel, K.P., Zapata, H. and Susanto, D. (2005) An Empirical Test of Environmental Kuznets Curve for Water Pollution. Environmental and Resource Economics, 31, 325-348.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10640-005-1544-5
[9] Barua, A. and Hubacek, K. (2009) An Empirical Analysis of the Environmental Kuznets Curve for Water Pollution in India. International Journal of Global Environmental Issues, 9, 50-68.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1504/IJGENVI.2009.022084
[10] Lopez, R. (1994) The Environment as a Factor of Production: The Effects of Economic Growth and Trade Liberalization. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 27, 163-184.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1006/jeem.1994.1032
[11] Selden, T.M. and Song, D. (1994) Environmental Quality and Development: Is There an Environmental Kuznet’s Curve for Air Pollution? Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 27, 147-162. http://dx.doi.org/10.1006/jeem.1994.1031
[12] John, A. and Pecchenino, R. (1994) An Overlapping Generation Model of Growth and the Environment. Economic Journal, 104, 1393-1410. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2235455
[13] Brock, W.A. and Taylor, M.S. (2010) The Green Solow Model. Journal of Economic Growth, 15, 127-153. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10887-010-9051-0
[14] Andreoni, J. and Levinson, A. (2001) The Simple Analytics of the Environmental Kuznets Curve. Journal of Public Economics, 80, 269-286. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0047-2727(00)00110-9

Copyright © 2024 by authors and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

Creative Commons License

This work and the related PDF file are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.