Adam Smith’s Perfectly Competitive Market Is Not Pareto Efficient: A Dynamic Perspective

Abstract

The invisible hand of a perfectly competitive market refers to the self-regulating behavior of the market where if each consumer and producer are allowed to freely make their own choices, the market settles at an efficient outcome that is beneficial to all the individual members of the society and hence to the society as a whole. Two well-known facets of the invisible hand are generally mentioned in the economics literature—the first one is a static picture of a perfectly competitive market, i.e. a competitive market is efficient in an equilibrium; and the second one is that if the competitive market is disturbed from its equilibrium position, in the absence of a market failure and frictions, the market automatically settles at a new efficient equilibrium. Existing literature does not consider the most important dynamic facet of the perfectly competitive market from the perspective of Pareto efficiency, i.e. how efficient is a perfectly competitive market on the dynamic adjustment path after an economic shock in the absence of all kinds of frictions and price rigidities, and if all the ideal conditions are maintained. This research models the dynamic facet of the market and concludes that Adam Smith’s perfectly competitive market is not Pareto efficient and coordinated actions of economic agents can result in a level of economic efficiency on the dynamic adjustment path which is not achievable by a free market mechanism (JEL D40, D41, D50, E32).

Share and Cite:

Ahmed, M. and Nawaz, N. (2023) Adam Smith’s Perfectly Competitive Market Is Not Pareto Efficient: A Dynamic Perspective. Theoretical Economics Letters, 13, 419-450. doi: 10.4236/tel.2023.133028.

1. Introduction

Adam Smith’s invisible hand was a clever mechanism for describing how information, idiosyncratic and dispersed among individuals, is accumulated and combined by the market mechanism such that the overall market equilibrium is the same as that would be obtained by an all-knowing social planner. This result is the core principle of all modern Samuelsonion welfare economics. However, the existing literature inadequately addresses the efficiency issue on the dynamic adjustment path of the market after an economic shock before it arrives at a new efficient equilibrium, and rather an adjustment mechanism has never been defined clearly for a perfectly competitive market. There is an inherent limitation in the definition of a perfectly competitive market, which precludes the explanation of the movement of the market price after an economic shock. In a perfectly competitive market, all producers are price takers and the prices are perfectly flexible, however, a central question to the discussion is: who changes the price after an economic shock to the market to lead to a new equilibrium? If no one changes the price, then supply will never equalize the demand after an economic shock, resulting in an infinite level of inefficiency. If the producers have to be assumed of changing the price when the market is out of equilibrium, it comes in direct conflict with the assumption of the producers being “price takers”. No other market agents (responsible for the movement of prices) have been defined under the theoretical concept of a perfectly competitive market. In this scenario, it is impossible to provide a theoretical framework for some drifting mechanisms for a perfectly competitive market from one equilibrium to the other, as the “price taking” and the “price changing” assumptions contradict each other. A producer cannot be a “price taker” and a “price changer” at the same time, however, with the only assumption of “price-taking behavior”, the market will logically get stuck in an “out of equilibrium” state for an infinite period of time leading to an infinite level of inefficiency, whereas, the assumption of a “price changer” for a market agent (which is inevitable to explain the change in price from one equilibrium to the other) implies at least a minimal level of market power. This also implies that a perfectly competitive market has to incur some inefficiency after an economic shock, i.e. either it gets stuck in an “out of equilibrium” state (under the agents’ price-taking assumption) or a market agent changes the price to bring the new equilibrium, in which case, the transition cannot occur free of cost and has to come at the expense of some economic efficiency!

The only way a perfectly competitive market can be efficient during the transition is that the economic shock itself instantly settles the price and quantity from one equilibrium to the other, i.e. the market jumps from one equilibrium to the other as a result of a shock through some magic wand. However, the basis of the market mechanism is self-interest by economic agents, which acts as a driving force to push the market toward an efficient equilibrium. When the market is in equilibrium, demand equals supply, however, after an economic shock the market does not instantaneously settle at a new equilibrium, the market forces once again become operative to drive the market and the market follows some adjustment process to move to the new equilibrium. The demand does not equal the supply throughout the adjustment process and there is some efficiency loss before the market settles at an efficient equilibrium. An important question to consider is: Can the market mechanism itself minimize this loss or is there some other mechanism that may improve the efficiency during the adjustment process? In order to address this question, we first need to quantify the efficiency of the dynamic adjustment path, and then compare it with an ideal situation.

Suppose there is only one producer in a market who produces a perishable good and sells it to the consumers living in a community. He sells a quantity exactly equal to the quantity he produces in each time period, and the market stays in equilibrium. If a demand shock decreases the demand for his product, some of his production will remain unsold and be wasted by the end of the time period in which the demand shock happened. Assuming that the producer can change the price and the production immediately, had he known the exact pattern of new demand, he would immediately pick the price and the quantity to maximize his profits and clear the market without wasting his production. However, he lacks this information, so he decreases the price based on his best guess about the new demand (based on the quantity of his unsold production), driving the market close to the new equilibrium. If in the next time period, his production is sold out, he will know that the new equilibrium has arrived, however, if a part of his production still remains unsold, he will reduce the price further (and production accordingly) to bring the market closer to the new equilibrium. The market will eventually settle at the new equilibrium after some efficiency loss. The resources wasted by the market mechanism are those which went into the unsold production in each time period during the adjustment process.

In contrast, suppose that after a demand shock, a community coordinator conveys information about the new demand at various prices to the producer. The producer would immediately pick the profit-maximizing, market-clearing price and quantity without an efficiency loss. The new equilibrium will be identical in both scenarios, however, coordination seems to improve upon the market mechanism during the adjustment process, by revealing the information of new demand to the producer, which is missing in the market where consumers only care about their self-interest without being bothered about the resources the producer will have to waste as unsold production on account of lack of this information. Therefore, coordination can improve upon the market mechanism in terms of efficiency during the adjustment process, even though the new equilibrium is going to be the same as that would be achieved by the market mechanism.

In the above example, only one producer was assumed just to make intuition simple and clear, however, the same reasoning goes through for a perfectly competitive market with a large number of buyers and suppliers. In a perfectly competitive market, the exact magnitude of an economic shock is not known to suppliers, and they also lack information on how consumers are going to respond to a specific shock. They try to gauge the intensity of the shock by increasing or decreasing the size of their inventories and adjusting their economic actions accordingly. However, if there is coordination among producers and consumers, producers have more information about the new economic scenario and the adjustment to the new equilibrium is smoother and quicker as compared to the adjustment in a free market. It would be too imaginative to believe that there can be such perfect coordination among all buyers and suppliers which may result in a zero efficiency loss after an economic shock, however, coordination can certainly improve economic efficiency during the adjustment process through mutual sharing of information among buyers and suppliers. There might arise issues of coordination costs, however, if the magnitude of shock is large enough and the adjustment process is associated with huge efficiency losses (which if saved could more than compensate coordination costs) then coordination is superior to a free market, whereas if the magnitude of shock is too small and coordination costs are comparatively too high, then the free market might lead to a more efficient adjustment process. There could also be positive externalities of coordination. These issues need to be discussed separately in future research projects.

The issue of economic efficiency has much been discussed in the previous literature. The Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics are generally stated in a form attributed to Arrow et al. (1952) , Arrow and Debreu (1954) and Debreu (1959) . Interpreting the conditions under which the First Theorem is true provides the basis of the Market Failure approach. Bator (1958) focuses on exter­nalities, natural monopolies, and public goods. Akerlof (1970) explains quality uncertainty as another source of market failure. Kaldor (1972) argues that the general economic equilibrium originally formulated by Walras and mathematically developed by Gerard Debreu is too over simplistic to depict real-world phenomena. Green (1977) discusses the non-existence of informational equilibria. Grossman and Stiglitz (1980) also model situations where a competitive equilibrium would not exist. Greenwald and Stiglitz (1986) argue that in general when risk markets are incomplete and information is imperfect, markets are not constrained Pareto optimal: the Invisible Hand does not work. In Stiglitz’s (1991) words: “The Welfare Theorems are just that: theorems, the conclusions of which follow inevitably from the assumptions. The research of the last two decades has not detected any major flaws in logic. The Theorems stand, as I have said, as one of the triumphs of modern mathematical economics. The question is not the logical status of these propositions, but their empirical relevance, the inferences which we make concerning how society should be organized and about the design of economic policy. These are, to be sure, matters of judgment. The earlier analyses of market failures basically agreed with the underlying conception of the market economy that was reflected in the assumptions of the Welfare Theorems. I am not so convinced”. Ackerman, Nadal, and Gallagher (2004) also call into question the assumptions in Arrow and Debreu’s analysis which make the Theorems of limited relevance to modern industrial economies.

There is also a huge literature discussing the efficiency of markets in the context of a society, e.g. D’Arge and Hunt (1971) argue that for economic efficiency, what needs to be accomplished is a persuasion of the populace away from the doctrine of self-interest and toward a doctrine of cooperation and conservation. Sen (1993) argues that competitive market equilibria are weakly efficient in opportunity freedoms in terms of capabilities as well as commodity holdings. Oakley et al. (1997) based on Titmus’ famous study on paid and unpaid blood donations explain the social repercussions of creating a market for blood, inviting an unending debate on the issue. Frey and Oberholzer-Gee (1997) develop the argument further to show how the market mechanism for certain entities undermines an individual’s sense of civic duty. Sunstein (1999) presents a new conception of the relationship between free markets and social justice. Folbre and Nelson (2000) elaborate that the market mechanism is unlikely to provide the quantum and quality of children, sick and elderly care. George (2004) challenges the view that free choice, as revealed by the preferences of individuals, maximizes the welfare of individuals given their income and market prices. Howell (2004) challenges the free market with regard to the labor markets around the world and persistent unemployment. Dolfsma, Finch, and McMaster (2005) argue how the conceptualization of the market in relation to society undermines the mainstream, Paretian perspective on welfare. Dolfsma (2005) highlights the importance of dynamic welfare. Satz (2010) delivers a comprehensive theory of the limits of the markets with regard to society. Hemsley-Brown (2011) portrays the challenges of a free market in higher education.

As the major focus of this paper is the efficiency of the dynamic adjustment path, it will not be out of place to acknowledge the previous literature highlighting the importance of the adjustment path to equilibrium. Diamond (1971) develops a model of price adjustment assuming that firms know the demands they face. Eden (1981) explains a theory of competitive price adjustment. Hahn (1984) explains why a theory of the economy out of equilibrium is required. David (2007) emphasizes the importance of path dependence in economics. Nerlove (1958) discusses the Cobweb model which explains why prices might be subject to periodic fluctuations in certain types of markets. The Cobweb model is based on adaptive expectations and is subject to criticism by the advocates of rational expectations. Herings (1996) gives a price adjustment process for an exchange economy that converges generically to Walrasian equilibrium. Tuinstra (2004) provides a price adjustment process in a model of monopolistic competition. There have been a number of ways of modeling paths to equilibrium under different sets of frictions, such as incomplete markets (see Angeletos & Calvet, 2005 ; Talman & Thijssen, 2006 ), adjustment costs (see Lucas, 1967 ; Bertola & Caballero, 1990 ; Danziger, 1999 ; Chen, Feng, & Seshadri, 2014 ), rational inattention (see Chen, Levy, Ray, & Bergen, 2008 ; Maćkowiak & Wiederholt, 2009, 2011 ), and search costs (see Wright, 1986 ), etc. Nawaz (2017, 2019a, 2019b, 2020, 2021, 2022) model dynamic adjustment path for optimal policies.

The main contribution of this paper is that the commonly believed notion that if all the ideal conditions of a perfectly competitive market are maintained, the market is Pareto efficient has been challenged to the extent of a dynamic adjustment path. It is shown that the market mechanism involves an efficiency loss during the adjustment process on account of agents’ lack of perfect information about the new economic conditions after the shock. In the existing literature, imperfect information generally refers to the asymmetric information among buyers and suppliers regarding the quality of a product or other factors leading either to an inefficient equilibrium or the non-existence of an equilibrium. This paper shows that even though an equilibrium exists, the free market cannot get rid of inefficiency on the way to equilibrium. This paper assumes perfect information regarding the quality of goods, just to distinguish and highlight the key point. The main source of inefficiency during the adjustment process is the agents’ lack of perfect information about the exact magnitude of the shock and the new patterns of supply and demand. The only way a perfectly competitive market can be Pareto efficient during the adjustment process after an economic shock is that if all the ideal conditions of a perfectly competitive market are maintained and also if all the economic agents have perfect information about the exact magnitude and direction of all future shocks and the exact patterns of supply and demand in an economy as a result of shocks for all times, which would have been possible only if economic agents were Gods, hence making the study of economics needless!

When the term market is used in economics, it generally refers to the two main economic agents, i.e. the consumer and the producer. The producer produces a product and sells it to the consumer for profit who has some willingness to pay for the product for consumption. In this way, a mutual exchange takes place between the two agents which is beneficial for both of them. However, in the real world these two economic agents seldom directly meet each other for a transaction to take place. Consumers never go to the factory owners to buy products. Borrowers never directly meet lenders. Students do not visit their professors’ houses to get an education. Each transaction between a consumer and a producer takes place through the involvement of a middleman. In the real world, wholesalers, retailers, financial institutions, educational institutions and hospitals, etc., reflect the very much presence of the middleman in the market. A market model in the absence of a middleman cannot capture the important aspects of reality. So, if the middleman is out there in the real world between a consumer and a producer, why not include it in the analysis and see how the static, as well as the dynamic market behavior, responds to the presence of a middleman?

In this paper, we develop a deterministic dynamic market model (for a single homogeneous commodity) in a continuous time framework. The model takes into account a supply curve, a demand curve, an inventory curve for the middleman, and dead time to model sticky prices and production frictions. However, the analytical solution to the model has been presented for the simple case when prices are perfectly flexible and there is no production friction. A more realistic case, which incorporates price rigidities and frictions, will be presented in a future research project.

The model answers the following research questions: How do actions of three market agents, i.e. consumer, producer and middleman in their own interest lead to the market equilibrium? Which path does the market follow as a result of an endogenous or exogenous shock in the steady-state equilibrium? How efficient is the market on that path? Can a free market on its own minimize efficiency losses during the adjustment process or is there any other mechanism that can help improve upon the market in terms of efficiency during the adjustment process? The model is based on mathematical formulations (in the time domain) of the practical behavior of key agents (without over-simplistic assumptions) endogenously capturing the feedback effects of price changes on the market system. A mathematical innovation in the model is the introduction of deviation variables, i.e. deviation from equilibrium (before shock) instead of the absolute value of the variable. This makes the model free of initial conditions as the initial value of a deviation variable is always zero.

The mathematical picture provides concrete conditions for the existence of an equilibrium that is independent of the middleman’s response. This result is supported by the final steady-state equilibrium (mathematical) expression which is dependent just on the responses of consumer and producer. The parameter depicting the middleman’s response drops out of the final steady-state equilibrium expression. However, the mathematical analysis shows that the middleman has an important role in the dynamic adjustment process. The response of the middleman (along with that of consumer and producer) determines the adjustment path of the market after an economic shock. The middleman’s response also determines the quantum of inefficiency during the adjustment process. The concept of dynamic efficiency has been discussed in the paper. When an economic shock hits the market, the market remains out of equilibrium during the adjustment period before it arrives at a new equilibrium. The longer the adjustment period, the greater the efficiency losses. The market certainly cannot and does not jump to a new equilibrium (an ideal dynamic efficiency condition that is not achievable). A market is said to be closer to an ideal dynamically efficient state if it follows the smoothest and the shortest possible route between equilibriums after an economic shock, that is, if it minimizes the present value of output (and/or consumption, utility) lost. The model provides a basic framework for a dynamic welfare analysis and scope for extensions and applications in various goods, services, labor and financial markets.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2 explains how the individual components of the market system are joined together to form a dynamic market model. Section 3 provides a solution to the model in the time domain when the market has no production friction and price rigidities. Section 4 summarizes the findings and concludes. Section 5 explains the future research prospects.

2. Model

The basic model has already been discussed in Nawaz (2017, 2019a, 2019b, 2020, 2021, 2022) . Let’s assume that there is a perfectly competitive market of a single homogeneous commodity in equilibrium (initial condition is when the market is already in equilibrium). There are three types of infinitely-lived agents: a representative or a unit mass of producer (that produces a good, and demands labor and capital), a middleman (who buys the good from firms to sell to consumers, and possibly accumulates inventories), and a representative or a unit mass of consumer (who buys the good, accumulates capital by investing and supplies labor inelastically). The role of middleman is motivated by real-world scenarios where producers and consumers seldom directly meet for a transaction to take place. The existence of retailers, wholesalers, financial institutions, educational institutions and hospitals reflects the presence of middlemen between producers and consumers in most of the economic activity going on. The producer produces the goods and supplies those to the middleman, who keeps an inventory of goods and sells to the consumer at the market price. In the model, the middleman plays a key role, as he sets the selling price p by maximizing the difference between the revenue for selling goods to consumers and the costs of inventories. The buying price paid to the producer is α p with α < 1 , and the producer is a price taker.

The price adjustment mechanism is based on the fact that when a shock leads the market out of equilibrium, the buyers’ and sellers’ decisions are not coordinated at the current prices. An example can illustrate the working of this market. Consider that the market is initially in equilibrium. The middleman has an equilibrium stock of inventory. Then, an exogenous demand contraction will increase the stock of inventory, due to firms’ output could not match with the now lower units demanded by the consumer at the current price. This excess of supply is accumulated in inventory held by the middleman. The middleman will decrease the price so that the producer will find optimal to produce a lower level of output. A new equilibrium with a lower price and a lower level of output is then reached. The equilibrium is defined as follows:

1) The producer and the middleman maximize their profits and the consumer maximizes utility subject to the constraints they face (mentioned in their individual dynamic optimization problems in Section 2).

2) The quantity supplied by the producer equals the quantity consumed by the consumer (and hence the inventory does not change when the market is in equilibrium).

The conditions for the existence of the equilibrium (Routh-Hurwitz stability criterion, which provides a necessary and sufficient condition for the stability of a linear dynamical system) have been mentioned in Section 3.

As the set up is for a perfectly competitive market, therefore, the middleman who sells the goods to the consumer at the market price is a price taker when the market is in equilibrium. When the market is out of equilibrium, the middleman can change the price along the dynamic adjustment path until the new equilibrium arrives, where again the middleman becomes a price taker. If a demand or supply shock hits the market, the market does not suddenly jump to a new equilibrium, rather the price adjusts over time to bring the new equilibrium. This adjustment process involves endogenous decision making (in their own interest) by all agents in the market, i.e. consumer, producer and the middleman. For the mathematical treatment, the objective of each of the three market agents is maximized through the first order conditions of their objective functions and to capture the collective result of their individual actions, the equations representing their individual actions are solved simultaneously. For simplification, we assume that after the shock, the new equilibrium is not too far from the initial equilibrium. This assumption makes the linearization of supply and demand curves quite reasonable. Please look at Figure 1 (the time axis is not shown). Linearization seems to be a good approximation when market moves from point a to b, whereas it is not a good approximation when it moves from point a to c. For modeling the movement of the market from point a to c, we need to model a non-linear dynamical system (which is not covered under the scope of this paper).

A small segment of the economy under study may be called as a system and everything else (which the system is to interact with) may be called as surroundings. Analysis of a system may be convenient if the system is sub-divided into

Figure 1. When is linearity a reasonable assumption?

smaller simpler components, which could be interconnected through their inputs/outputs. A mathematical equation correlating outputs with inputs may be written for each component giving a set of simultaneous equations. Solution of this set of equations may give an overall behavior of the system.

A block diagram representation is a convenient tool for giving an overall picture of the relationships among variables by highlighting the function of each component and the flow of information around the system. A block indicates a mathematical operation or procedure applied on an input to generate an output. Let us consider the following function:

Y = f ( X ) . (1)

This function can be represented by the rectangular block shown in Figure 2. The arrow entering the box is the forcing function or input variable, and the arrow leaving the box is the response or output variable. Inside the box is placed the function. We state that the function in the box operates on the input function X to produce an output function Y. The rectangular block can be used to represent a component of the system, which transforms its input to an output. X and Y may or may not be the physical input and output respectively.

Concept of dead time:

Sometimes, there is a time gap involved between receiving an information and making a decision or taking an action. This time gap may be called as dead time or time of inaction. Suppose some information or material is sent to us through a postal or courier service. We receive information or material without a change in it but after a delay in time. In Figure 3, f ( t ) and f ( t τ d ) are identical

Figure 2. Block diagram representation of input and output.

Figure 3. Concept of Dead Time.

but f ( t τ d ) is delayed by time τ d . a and a' are two corresponding points on f ( t ) and f ( t τ d ) . a' appears after a with a time delay of τ d ( a a = τ d ). Dead time element may be represented by the rectangular block given in Figure 4. The involvement of dead time means that the basis of implementation is back dated. Sometimes information is prompt but its implementation is delayed due to practical reasons. At times information is delayed but the implementation is prompt. In certain other situations both information and its implementation are delayed. As the impact of each situation is the same (i.e. implementation is based on back dated information or happening), therefore, the mathematical handling of each of these cases is the same.

A market system may be sub-divided into the following three physical entities: 1) the producer, 2) the middleman and 3) the consumer.

2.1. Middleman

The middleman purchases goods from producer and sells to consumer for profit. As happens in the real world, the middleman does not buy and sell exactly the same quantity at all points in time, thus he holds an inventory of the goods purchased to be sold subsequently. Inventory is an intermediary stage between supply and demand which reflects the quantum of difference between supply and demand of the goods in the market. If the inventory remains the same, it implies that demand and supply rates are the same. An increase or decrease in inventory implies a change in supply, demand or both at different rates.

Figure 5 illustrates the link among inventory, supply, demand and prices. When supply curve shifts to the right (while demand remains the same), inventory in the market increases at initial price, and new equilibrium brings price down. Similarly, when demand curve shifts to the right (while supply remains the same), inventory depletes from the market at previous price and new equilibrium brings price up. This shows that there is an inverse relationship between an inventory change and a price change (all else the same). If both supply and demand curves shift by the same magnitude such that the inventory does not change, then price will also remain the same. Inventory unifies supply and demand shocks in the sense that they are both affecting the same factor, i.e. inventory and are basically the faces of the same coin. Therefore, each kind of shock is in fact just an inventory shock. From above mentioned discussion, we have seen that there is an inverse relationship between an inventory change and a price change.

Now, let’s discuss the mechanism which brings about such a change. Consider

Figure 4. Dead Time between input and output.

Figure 5. Movement of price with inventory.

a market of homogeneous goods where the middlemen, such as whole sellers, retailers, etc., hold inventories, incur some cost for holding those, and sell products to the consumers to make profits. Cost is a positive function of the size of an inventory, i.e. a larger inventory costs more to hold as compared to a smaller inventory. In absence of an exogenous shock, if supply and demand rates are equal then the system is in equilibrium and the price does not vary with time. Suppose that a technological advancement decreases the marginal cost of production and increases supply rate, whereas demand rate remains the same. As demand and supply rates are no longer equal, therefore, the difference will appear somewhere in the economy in the form of piled up inventories. As the production flows from producer to consumer through the middleman, therefore, it is reasonable to assume that the middleman will be holding the net difference (Explanation: The piled up inventories can also be in the form of producers’ inventories of finished goods, which does not change the key point that a difference of supply and demand rates directly affect the inventories in the economy). The economy will not be able to sustain this situation for an indefinite time period, and the middlemen will have to think of some means of getting rid of piled up inventories. The only resort they have is to decrease the price which brings the demand up along the demand curve.

In a perfectly competitive market, price will eventually come down to equalize the new marginal cost, however the adjustment path depends on how the middlemen react to the change in their inventories. Notice that the marginal cost of production has decreased but the marginal cost of holding an extra unit of inventory for the middleman has increased. This is an intuitive explanation which is theoretically consistent with the demand, supply, utility and profit maximization by a consumer and a producer respectively. In the real world, we see examples of this behavior of middlemen, e.g. as consumers, we enjoy end of year sales, offers such as buy one get one free, gift offers if you buy above a certain quantity threshold, etc. For a mathematical treatment, we need to consider profit maximization problem of the middleman as follows.

2.1.1. Short-Term Problem

Let’s first consider the short-term problem, i.e. the middleman’s objective is myopic rather than doing dynamic optimization. In a discrete analog, this is a one period analysis, which is presented for an intuitive purpose in anticipation of the (more complicated) dynamic problem in Section 2.1.2. Expression for middleman’s profit is as follows:

Π = p q ( p ) ς ( m ( p , e ) ) , (2)

where:

Π = profit,

p = market price,

q(p) = quantity sold at price p,

m = inventory (total number of goods held by the middleman),

e = factors which influence inventory other than the market price including middleman’s purchase price from producer,

ς ( m ( p , e ) ) = cost as a function of inventory (increasing in inventory).

First order condition (with respect to price) is as follows:

p q ( p ) + q ( p ) ς ( m ( p , e ) ) m 1 ( p , e ) = 0. (3)

Middleman has an incentive to change price only during the adjustment process and will incur losses by deviating from the price (equal to marginal cost) when market is in equilibrium. During adjustment process, demand does not equal supply and the market drifts toward the new equilibrium (however, price cannot move automatically and it is reasonable to assume that some economic agent moves price in his own benefit), therefore, a price change by middleman in the direction of bringing new equilibrium is not against market forces, so he does not lose business by changing price on the adjustment path unlike when the market is in equilibrium and where the middleman faces an infinitely elastic demand as follows:

p q ( p ) + q ( p ) = ς ( m ( p , e ) ) m 1 ( p , e ) ,

p [ 1 + 1 demandelasticity ] = ς ( m ( p , e ) ) m 1 ( p , e ) q ( p ) .

The right hand side of above expression is the marginal cost which equals price when the middleman faces an infinitely elastic demand. Suppose that as a result of a supply shock, the marginal cost of production decreases, and the supply curve shifts downwards. Now, the competitive market is out of equilibrium as demand does not equal supply at the previous equilibrium price. The price must eventually decrease to bring the new equilibrium, however, the price will not jump to equalize demand and supply, and rather the middleman will continue charging a price higher than the new marginal cost until the market forces make him realize that the supply has increased and he needs to lower the price to satisfy profit maximization condition. The similar is the case of a reverse supply shock, where price must eventually increase to bring new equilibrium. In this case, the middleman will continue charging a price lower than the marginal cost until the market forces make him increase price, in which case it is the consumer who is the short term beneficiary. Again, the consumer will be paying a price less than the marginal cost only during the adjustment process and only until the middleman increases the price. The equilibrium price is equal to marginal cost of production plus the marginal cost of storage (i.e. total marginal cost) in absence of any kind of a tax, so neither does middleman earn any economic rent, nor does consumer benefit by paying a price less than marginal cost when competitive market is in equilibrium.

For mathematical treatment, suppose as a result of a supply shock (while demand remains the same) such as a technological advancement which reduces marginal cost of production and increases supply by producers, if the middleman wants to hold an extra unit of inventory, his marginal cost of holding an extra unit i.e. ς ( m ( p , e ) ) m 1 ( p , e ) q ( p ) is higher at the previous price, because the term ς ( m ( p , e ) ) is higher at the previous price. This might be on account of higher storage charges because of increased demand of warehouses, godowns, etc. after increased supply in the market. The second term, i.e. m 1 ( p , e ) q ( p ) is a function of price, and is the same as before as the price has not changed yet (we are assuming that middleman’s purchase price is the same as before as producer is a price taker during the adjustment process as well and always charges a fixed fraction of market price to middleman). A discrete analog of this scenario is that middleman maximizes profits in each time period without considering future time periods, and in each time period he takes the purchase price from producer as given and only chooses the sale price. This implies that on the previous price, now middleman faces

Π p = p q ( p ) + q ( p ) ς ( m ( p , e ) ) m 1 ( p , e ) < 0 , (4)

which means that middleman must decrease price to hold an extra unit of inventory to satisfy the profit maximization condition after the supply shock. Note, that in this static scenario, the short term gains accrued from decreased marginal cost of production will be reaped by producer, as his marginal cost has decreased but he charges the same price to middleman until the middleman changes the price. If we plot together various profit maximizing combinations of inventories and respective prices chosen by middleman, a downward sloping inventory curve results with price on y-axis and inventory on x-axis. This is analogous to the concept of supply and demand curves for profit maximizing producers and utility maximizing consumers respectively.

2.1.2. Dynamic Problem

Now, let’s consider the dynamic problem of middleman. In a dynamic setting, middleman maximizes present discounted value of future stream of profits, and his present value at time zero is as follows:

V ( 0 ) = 0 [ p q ( p ) ς ( m ( p , e ) ) ] e r t d t , (5)

where r denotes the discount rate, p ( t ) is control variable; and m ( t ) the state variable. The maximization problem can be written as

max { p ( t ) } V ( 0 ) = 0 [ p q ( p ) ς ( m ( p , e ) ) ] e r t d t ,

subject to the constraints that

m ˙ ( t ) = m 1 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) p ˙ ( t ) + m 2 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) e 1 ( p ( t ) , z ) p ˙ ( t ) (state equation, describing how state variable changes with time; z are exogenous factors),

m ( 0 ) = m s (initial condition),

m ( t ) 0 (non-negativity constraint on state variable),

m ( ) free (terminal condition).

The current-value Hamiltonian for this case is

H ˜ = p ( t ) q ( p ( t ) ) ς ( m ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) ) + μ ( t ) p ˙ ( t ) [ m 1 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) + m 2 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) e 1 ( p ( t ) , z ) ] . (6)

Now, the maximizing conditions are as follows:

1) p ( t ) maximizes H ˜ for all t: H ˜ p = 0 ,

2) μ ˙ r μ = H ˜ m ,

3) m ˙ = H μ (this just gives back the state equation),

4) l i m t μ ( t ) m ( t ) e r t = 0 (the transversality condition).

The first two conditions are as follows:

H ˜ p = q ( p ( t ) ) + p ( t ) q ( p ( t ) ) ς ( m ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) ) { m 1 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) + m 2 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) e 1 ( p ( t ) , z ) } + μ ( t ) p ˙ ( t ) [ m 11 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) + m 12 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) e 1 ( p ( t ) , z ) + m 21 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) e 1 ( p ( t ) , z ) + m 22 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) e 1 2 ( p ( t ) , z ) + m 2 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) e 11 ( p ( t ) , z ) ] = 0, (7)

and

μ ˙ r μ = H ˜ m = ς ( m ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) ) . (8)

When the market is in equilibrium, p ˙ ( t ) = 0 , and the expression H ˜ p boils down to the following:

q ( p ( t ) ) + p ( t ) q ( p ( t ) ) ς ( m ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) ) { m 1 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) + m 2 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) e 1 ( p ( t ) , z ) } = 0,

p ( t ) [ 1 + 1 demandelasticity ] = ς ( m ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) ) { m 1 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) q ( p ( t ) ) + m 2 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) e 1 ( p ( t ) , z ) q ( p ( t ) ) } ,

suggesting that price equals marginal cost (the right hand side of above expression is marginal cost in a dynamic setting, which is different from that in a short-term problem due to the fact that in a dynamic setting, middleman also considers the impact of price chosen on his purchase price from producer) when demand is infinitely elastic. Now, suppose that as a result of a supply shock, if middleman wants to hold an extra unit of inventory, then the marginal cost of holding an extra unit is higher because the term ς ( m ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) ) is higher at the previous price at that point in time. The term in parentheses in the expression for marginal cost, i.e.

m 1 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) q ( p ( t ) ) + m 2 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) e 1 ( p ( t ) , z ) q ( p ( t ) ) is a function of price and is the same at the previous price. This implies that on the previous price, now the middleman faces

H ˜ p = q ( p ( t ) ) + p ( t ) q ( p ( t ) ) ς ( m ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) ) { m 1 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) + m 2 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) e 1 ( p ( t ) , z ) } + μ ( t ) p ˙ ( t ) [ m 11 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) + m 12 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) e 1 ( p ( t ) , z ) + m 21 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) e 1 ( p ( t ) , z ) + m 22 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) e 1 2 ( p ( t ) , z ) + m 2 ( p ( t ) , e ( p ( t ) , z ) ) e 11 ( p ( t ) , z ) ] < 0.

Therefore, in order to satisfy the condition of dynamic optimization, middleman must decrease price for an increase in inventory. This implies there is a negative relationship between price and inventory. The concept of inventory unifies market supply and demand. If supply and demand rates are equal, market is in a steady-state equilibrium. If a difference of finite magnitude is created between supply and demand rates and consumer and producer do not react to a price change induced by a difference in supply and demand rates, price will continue changing until the system saturates. This behavior can be depicted by the following formulation:

Pricechange changeinmarketinventory .

P = pricechange .

M = m m s = changeininventoryinthemarket,

m = inventoryattime t ,

m s = inventoryinsteadystateequilibrium .

Input output = d m d t = d ( m m s ) d t = d M d t ,

or M = ( input output ) d t .

Pricechange ( supplyrate demandrate ) d t , or

P = K m ( supplyrate demandrate ) d t ,

where K m is the proportionality constant; supply and demand rate is the supply and demand per unit time respectively. A negative sign indicates that when ( supplyrate demandrate ) is positive, P is negative (i.e. price decreases). The above equation can be re-arranged as follows:

( supplyrate demandrate ) d t = P K m , or

( w i w 0 ) d t = P K m , (9)

wi = supply rate,

w0 = demand rate,

Km = dimensional constant.

Let at time t = 0 , supply rate = demand rate (market is in a steady-state equilibrium), then Equation (9) can be written as

( w i s w 0 s ) d t = 0. (10)

The subscript s indicates the steady-state equilibrium and P = 0 in steady state. Subtracting Equation (10) from Equation (9), we get:

( w i w i s ) d t ( w 0 w 0 s ) d t = P K m , or

( W i W 0 ) d t = P K m , (11)

where w i w i s = W i = change in supply rate,

w 0 w 0 s = W 0 = change in demand rate.

P , W i and W 0 are deviation variables, which indicate deviation from the steady-state equilibrium. The initial values of the deviation variables are zero. Equation (11) may also be written as follows:

P = K m W d t = K m M , (12)

where W = W i W 0 . In the above analysis, we have assumed that P instantly responds to M. In reality, P persists for a while say τ d 1 until the middleman realizes that there is a shortage or surplus of a commodity. The middleman is reluctant to change the price during this time without confirming the fact whether trend is transitory or permanent. Thus, a dead time element is needed to be introduced after the rectangular block in Figure 6 which modifies it to Figure 7.

2.2. Producer

Producer maximizes present discounted value of future stream of profits, and his present value at time zero is as follows:

V ( 0 ) = 0 [ α p ( t ) F ( K ( t ) , L ( t ) ) w ( t ) L ( t ) ( t ) I ( t ) ] e r t d t , (13)

α is fraction of market price the producer charges to middleman. r denotes the discount rate. L ( t ) (labor) and I ( t ) (level of investment) are control variables and K ( t ) the state variable. The maximization problem can be written as follows:

max { L ( t ) , I ( t ) } V ( 0 ) = 0 [ α p ( t ) F ( K ( t ) , L ( t ) ) w ( t ) L ( t ) ( t ) I ( t ) ] e r t d t ,

subject to the constraints that

K ˙ ( t ) = I ( t ) δ K ( t ) (state equation, describing how state variable changes with time),

K ( 0 ) = K 0 (initial condition),

K ( t ) 0 (non-negativity constraint on state variable),

K ( ) free (terminal condition).

Figure 6. Block of the middleman without Dead Time.

Figure 7. Block of the middleman with Dead Time.

The current-value Hamiltonian for this case is as given below:

H ˜ = α p ( t ) F ( K ( t ) , L ( t ) ) w ( t ) L ( t ) ( t ) I ( t ) + μ ( t ) [ I ( t ) δ K ( t ) ] . (14)

Now, the maximizing conditions are as follows:

1) L ( t ) and I ( t ) maximize H ˜ for all t: H ˜ L = 0 and H ˜ I = 0 ,

2) μ ˙ r μ = H ˜ K ,

3) K ˙ = H μ (this just gives back the state equation),

4) lim t μ ( t ) K ( t ) e r t = 0 (the transversality condition).

The first two conditions are as follows:

H ˜ L = α p ( t ) F 2 ( K ( t ) , L ( t ) ) w ( t ) = 0 , (15)

H ˜ I = ( t ) + μ ( t ) = 0 , (16)

and

μ ˙ r μ = H ˜ K = [ α p ( t ) F 1 ( K ( t ) , L ( t ) ) δ μ ( t ) ] . (17)

Substituting the value of μ ˙ and μ from Equation (16) into Equation (17) yields

α p ( t ) F 1 ( K ( t ) , L ( t ) ) ( r + δ ) ( t ) + ˙ ( t ) = 0.

If price, p ( t ) goes up, (at the previous level of investment and labor) producer faces following inequalities:

α p ( t ) F 2 ( K ( t ) , L ( t ) ) w ( t ) > 0 ,

α p ( t ) F 1 ( K ( t ) , L ( t ) ) ( r + δ ) ( t ) + ˙ ( t ) > 0.

Therefore, in order to satisfy condition of dynamic optimization after price increase, producer must increase production level. Let p = market price, c = a reference price (such as retail price which includes production cost, profit of producer and profit of middleman). c is a parameter which may vary with time or be kept fixed for a limited time period, e.g. cost of a product may vary over time or can also remain constant for a while. It is the reference point with respect to which variation in p is considered by producer for decision making.

W m = Changeinproductionduetochangeinprice,

( p c ) acts as an incentive for producer to produce more. We can write:

W m = F s ( α ( p c ) ) ,

F s is a function of α ( p c ) , which is assumed to be linear (or linearization of production function of price around steady-state equilibrium could lead to the similar expression) and leads to the following expression:

W m = K s ( p c ) , (18)

when market is in equilibrium, then W m = 0 , or

0 = K s ( p s c s ) . (19)

K s is being endogenously determined, and turned out to be a constant by virtue of linearization of F s around steady-state equilibrium (and whether F s is practically linear or non-linear is an empirical question). p s and c s are steady-state equilibrium values. Subtracting Equation (19) from Equation (18), we get:

W m = K s [ ( p p s ) ( c c s ) ] = K s ( C P ) = K s ε , (20)

where W m , C and P are deviation variables. Equation (20) can be represented by the block diagram in Figure 8 where it is assumed that producer instantly responds to market price; however, in reality extra time for planning and preparation to overcome technological and credit constraints is needed to change production, e.g. purchase or import of raw materials, enhancement of production capacity or waiting until the next season for seasonal agricultural products, etc., all necessitate dead time, i.e. τ d 2 (by definition). Therefore, Figure 8 should get amended to Figure 9.

2.3. Consumer

Consumer maximizes present discounted value of future stream of utilities, and his present value at time zero is as follows:

V ( 0 ) = 0 U ( x ( t ) ) e ρ t d t , (21)

ρ denotes the discount rate and x ( t ) is control variable. The maximization problem can be written as

max { x ( t ) } V ( 0 ) = 0 U ( x ( t ) ) e ρ t d t ,

Figure 8. Block of the producer without Dead Time.

Figure 9. Block of the producer with Dead Time.

subject to the constraints that

a ˙ ( t ) = R ( t ) a ( t ) + w ( t ) p ( t ) x ( t ) (state equation, describing how state variable changes with time). a ( t ) is asset holdings (a state variable) and w ( t ) and R ( t ) are exogenous time path of wages and return on assets.

a ( 0 ) = a s (initial condition),

a ( t ) 0 (non-negativity constraint on state variable),

a ( ) free (terminal condition).

The current-value Hamiltonian for this case is

H ˜ = U ( x ( t ) ) + μ ( t ) [ R ( t ) a ( t ) + w ( t ) p ( t ) x ( t ) ] . (22)

Now, the maximizing conditions are as follows:

1) x ( t ) maximizes H ˜ for all t: H ˜ x = 0 ,

2) μ ˙ ρ μ = H ˜ a ,

3) a ˙ = H μ (this just gives back the state equation),

4) lim t μ ( t ) a ( t ) e ρ t = 0 (the transversality condition).

The first two conditions are as follows:

H ˜ x = U ( x ( t ) ) μ ( t ) p ( t ) = 0, (23)

and

μ ˙ ρ μ = H ˜ a = μ ( t ) R ( t ) . (24)

If price of good x goes up, consumer faces (at the previous level of consumption) following inequality:

H ˜ x = U ( x ( t ) ) μ ( t ) p ( t ) < 0.

Therefore, in order to satisfy the condition of dynamic optimization after price increase, consumer must decrease consumption of good x.

Changeindemand = F d ( P ) .

Let change in demand be proportional to change in price, i.e. P, or equivalently linearization of demand function of price around the steady-state equilibrium leads to the following expression:

Changeindemand P , or

W d = K d P . (25)

W d is change in demand due to P; when P is positive W d is negative. Change in demand is endogenously determined as a result of a feedback of the price to consumer, and whether or not demand curve is linear is an empirical question. This equation can be represented by the block diagram in Figure 10. We combine Figure 7, Figure 9 and Figure 10 to get Figure 11 (our desired dynamic market model) where all variables are functions of time.

Figure 10. Block of the consumer.

Figure 11. Dynamic market model in block diagram representation.

3. Time Domain Solution with Flexible Prices and No Production Friction

The ideal scenario is when prices are perfectly flexible and there is no production friction, i.e. τ d 1 = τ d 2 = 0 . If τ d 1 is zero, price is adjustable without delay, and τ d 2 = 0 , implies that producer can adjust production without delay, which is possible if producer does not face any production friction. Let’s solve the model for this case as follows:

From Equations (12) and (25), we have the following expressions:

d P ( t ) d t = K m W ( t ) , (26)

W d ( t ) = K d P ( t ) , (27)

W ( t ) = W i ( t ) W 0 ( t ) + W m ( t ) W d ( t ) W 1 ( t ) W d ( t ) . (28)

W i ( t ) and W 0 ( t ) are exogenous supply and demand shocks respectively. We can solve the above equations simultaneously for P ( t ) in terms of W 1 ( t ) . Substituting W ( t ) from Equation (28) into Equation (26), we get:

d P ( t ) d t = K m [ W 1 ( t ) W d ( t ) ] .

Now, plugging Equation (27) into the above expression, we get:

d P ( t ) d t = K m [ W 1 ( t ) + K d P ( t ) ] , or

d P ( t ) d t + K m K d P ( t ) = K m W 1 ( t ) , (29)

where W 1 ( t ) = W i ( t ) W 0 ( t ) + W m ( t ) D ( t ) + W m ( t ) .

D ( t ) = W i ( t ) W 0 ( t ) = supplyratechange demandratechange .

D ( t ) captures the exogenous shocks. It will change either as a result of a demand shock, a supply shock or both. Now, including Equation (20) and assuming C ( t ) = 0 (i.e. production cost does not change), we have the following equations:

d P ( t ) d t + K m K d P ( t ) = K m [ D ( t ) + W m ( t ) ] , (30)

W m ( t ) = K s ε ( t ) , (31)

ε ( t ) = P ( t ) . (32)

Plugging Equation (32) into Equation (31) and then substituting the value of W m ( t ) into Equation (30), we get:

d P ( t ) d t + K m K d P ( t ) = K m [ D ( t ) + K s P ( t ) ] , or

d P ( t ) d t + K m ( K d + K s ) P ( t ) + K m D ( t ) = 0. (33)

The Routh-Hurwitz stability criterion (which provides a necessary and sufficient condition for stability of a linear dynamical system) for stability of above differential equation is K m ( K d + K s ) > 0 , which holds as K m , K d and K s are all defined to be positive. This ensures that, away from a given initial equilibrium, every adjustment mechanism will lead to another equilibrium. Laplace transform of the above expression gives:

P ( s ) D ( s ) = K m s + K m ( K s + K d ) . (34)

Suppose that a permanent supply (or demand) shock hits the market, i.e. D ( t ) = A . Substituting the transformed expression into the above equation, we get:

P ( s ) = A K m s [ s + K m ( K s + K d ) ] . (35)

Using the Final Value Theorem of Laplace transform, we get:

P ( ) = A K s + K d . (36)

It is evident from the above expression that the final steady-state equilibrium is dependent just on the responses of consumer and producer. The parameter, depicting the response of middleman, i.e. K m dropped out of the final steady-state equilibrium expression. Similarly using the Initial Value Theorem of Laplace transform on Equation (35), we get:

P ( 0 ) = 0. (37)

Now, let’s see how the response of the middleman affects the adjustment path when the prices are flexible and there is no production friction, that is, there is no dead time for middleman as well as for producer. Both these assumptions do not seem to be a depiction of the real world as prices are sticky in the short term in reality and the producers cannot instantaneously change production, however, the main purpose is to prove thesis of this research when all ideal conditions of a perfectly competitive market are met. Middleman can influence efficiency on dynamic adjustment path even if a perfectly competitive market is free of production frictions and short term price rigidities. Let’s consider the following three cases.

3.1. Case a

Let K m = 1 , K s = 1 , K d = 1 and A = 1 , then by Equation (33), we have

d P ( t ) d t + 2 P ( t ) = 1. (38)

The characteristic function for this differential equation is as follows:

x + 2 = 0, or

x = 2.

Thus, the complementary solution is

P c ( t ) = C 2 e 2 t .

The particular solution has the form

P p ( t ) = C 1 .

Thus, the solution has the form

P ( t ) = C 1 + C 2 e 2 t . (39)

The constant C 1 is determined by substitution into the differential equation as follows:

2 C 2 e 2 t + 2 C 1 + 2 C 2 e 2 t = 1 ,

C 1 = 0.5.

C 2 is determined by the initial condition as follows:

P ( 0 ) = 0.5 + C 2 = 0 ,

C 2 = 0.5.

Substituting the values of C 1 and C 2 in Equation (39), we get:

P ( t ) = 0.5 + 0.5 e 2 t . (40)

When t = 0 , P ( 0 ) = 0 (the initial condition), and when t = , P ( ) = 0.5 (the final steady-state equilibrium value). Both these values are consistent with Equation (36) and Equation (37).

3.2. Case b

Let K m = 2 , K s = 1 , K d = 1 and A = 1 , (only the value of K m has been changed from 1 to 2) then by Equation (33), we have

d P ( t ) d t + 4 P ( t ) = 2. (41)

The characteristic function for this differential equation is as follows:

x + 4 = 0, or

x = 4.

Thus, the complementary solution is

P c ( t ) = C 2 e 4 t .

The particular solution has the form

P p ( t ) = C 1 .

Thus, the solution has the form

P ( t ) = C 1 + C 2 e 4 t . (42)

The constant C 1 is determined by substitution into the differential equation as follows:

4 C 2 e 4 t + 4 C 1 + 4 C 2 e 4 t = 2,

C 1 = 0.5.

C 2 is determined by the initial condition as follows:

P ( 0 ) = 0.5 + C 2 = 0 ,

C 2 = 0.5.

Substituting the values of C 1 and C 2 in Equation (42), we get:

P ( t ) = 0.5 + 0.5 e 4 t . (43)

When t = 0 , P ( 0 ) = 0 (the initial condition), and when t = , P ( ) = 0.5 (the final steady-state equilibrium value). Both these values are consistent with Equation (36) and Equation (37).

3.3. Case c

Let K m = 4 , K s = 1 , K d = 1 and A = 1 , (only the value of K m has been changed to 4) then by Equation (33), we have

d P ( t ) d t + 8 P ( t ) = 4. (44)

The characteristic function for this differential equation is as follows:

x + 8 = 0, or

x = 8.

Thus, the complementary solution is

P c ( t ) = C 2 e 8 t .

The particular solution has the form

P p ( t ) = C 1 .

Thus, the solution has the form

P ( t ) = C 1 + C 2 e 8 t . (45)

The constant C 1 is determined by substitution into the differential equation as follows:

8 C 2 e 8 t + 8 C 1 + 8 C 2 e 8 t = 4 ,

C 1 = 0.5.

C 2 is determined by the initial condition as follows:

P ( 0 ) = 0.5 + C 2 = 0 ,

C 2 = 0.5.

Substituting the values of C 1 and C 2 in Equation (45), we get:

P ( t ) = 0.5 + 0.5 e 8 t . (46)

When t = 0 , P ( 0 ) = 0 (the initial condition), and when t = , P ( ) = 0.5 (the final steady-state equilibrium value). Both these values are consistent with Equation (36) and Equation (37). Figure 12 depicts the dynamics of the price of the market for all above three cases from one equilibrium to the other after an economic shock. In all above cases, we got the same steady-state equilibrium change, i.e. P ( ) = 0.5 . This is due to the fact that the responses of producer and consumer were kept fixed and the final steady-state equilibrium depends

Figure 12. Plot of P ( t ) versus t for cases a, b and c.

only on their responses as shown in Equation (36). However, as we increased the value of K m , which means changing the response of middleman ( K m is the slope of the inventory curve, a large value of K m in absolute sense, indicates that middleman changes price by a large magnitude for a small change in inventory), the system’s adjustment path to the new steady-state equilibrium changed. The vertical line in Figure 12 is for ideal dynamic efficiency, where the market jumps from one equilibrium to the next. This ideal dynamic efficiency is not achievable through any practical means, however, some options are better than others, e.g. case c is the closest to the ideal dynamic efficiency as compared to the other two cases, which shows that if middleman reacts strongly to the shock and changes price by a large magnitude for a small change in inventory (which is possible if three economic agents have better coordination with each other), the market will quickly adjust to the new equilibrium with smaller efficiency loss.

A pile up of inventory after an economic shock indicates a higher supply than demand, and a depletion of inventory occurs when demand is higher than supply in a given time period. When demand and supply are same, there is no efficiency loss. If demand and supply are different, output and/or consumption is being lost at that point in time. Therefore, if we sum up the inventory change at all points in time, we get total efficiency loss, which is as follows:

E L = 0 t [ W m ( t ) W d ( t ) ] d t = M ( t ) . (47)

The area under the curves in Figure 13 is the dynamic efficiency loss for all three cases, which is the smallest in case c (strong coordination) as compared to those for cases a (free market) and b (weak coordination). The characteristic function of Equation (33) has a single root given by:

Figure 13. Plot of [ W m ( t ) W d ( t ) ] versus t for cases a, b and c.

x = K m ( K s + K d ) = K .

If any of the Ks, i.e. K s , K d or K m (the slope of supply, demand or inventory curve respectively) increase, the root moves on negative real axis and away from the origin, so market response to the new equilibrium becomes faster. However, it is important to notice that K m is being multiplied by the sum of K s and K d , therefore, the middleman has a stronger role on adjustment path than that of producer or consumer.

4. Conclusion

When an economic shock hits a perfectly competitive market, the market remains out of equilibrium during the adjustment period before it arrives at a new steady-state equilibrium. The longer the adjustment period, the greater the efficiency losses. An ideal dynamically efficient market would jump from one equilibrium to the other after an economic shock, and the market would always stay in equilibrium without an efficiency loss, however, this ideal situation is not practically achievable. An achievable dynamic efficiency is the smoothest and the shortest possible route that the market may adopt to move to the new steady-state equilibrium after an economic shock. This path is determined by the collective action of all agents in the market, i.e. producer, middleman and consumer. A free market on its own cannot minimize efficiency loss during adjustment to the final equilibrium due to the lack of perfect information on the magnitude of shock and new patterns of supply and demand by economic agents. However, if the agents coordinate among themselves for their economic activity, they can minimize efficiency loss during the adjustment period.

Most transactions between producer and consumer take place through a middleman, therefore, the middleman can play a significant role during the adjustment process. As the middleman acts like a post office, the final equilibrium is determined only by the responses of the producer and consumer as shown in Equation (36). However, the middleman has an important role during the adjustment of the market. Suppose that after a demand shock (while supply remains the same), a consumer’s representative informs the middleman about a new demand pattern at various prices, middleman will be able to change price much more quickly and efficiently to bring final equilibrium as compared to that in a free market where middleman will get a signal of a demand shock only through a variation in the quantity of his inventory (because consumers are not obliged to inform middleman about their changed preferences), which will involve more time and efficiency loss before adjustment to new equilibrium takes place. Similarly, if a shock happens on the supply side (while demand remains the same), such as a marginal cost change due to some technological innovation, producers can lead to lower efficiency losses if they coordinate with the middleman through the provision of information about new marginal costs. The incentives for coordination may vary and there can be some short-term winners at the expense of others in a free market, however, coordination can improve overall economic efficiency on the adjustment path of the market to equilibrium. As equilibrium is a short-lived condition in a dynamic world where shocks happen quite frequently, efficiency during the adjustment of the market cannot be ignored.

A well-informed middleman can take stronger action regarding a change in price as a result of a change in inventory or even before an actual inventory change takes place. In all three cases mentioned in the previous section, only the response of the middleman has varied through the value of K m while the responses of the producer and consumer have been kept fixed. The dead times for the producer and middleman have been assigned zero values which imply flexible prices and no production friction (i.e. ideal conditions of a perfectly competitive market are maintained). The plot for Cases a (free market), b (weak coordination) and c (strong coordination), i.e. Figure 12 shows that the market arrives at the same new steady-state equilibrium in all three cases. However, increasing the value of K m (the slope of the inventory curve), which implies improved coordination among three agents, makes the transition to the new equilibrium as short as possible, thus bringing the market closer to the ideal dynamically efficient system. Like all natural systems, the market has a self-regulation property, however, it has certain limitations. In spite of the optimal behavior of economic agents, the market can never achieve an ideal dynamic efficiency as depicted in Figure 12. However, a transition path closer to the ideal situation (and practically achievable) is more desirable than others which is attainable through some coordinated actions by economic agents.

Future Research Prospects

Some potential future research areas are as follows:

Dynamic welfare analysis: A complete dynamic welfare analysis against various governmental policies is important and this research paper provides a foundation for that.

Extensions to various kinds of markets in economy: This paper serves as a fundamental unit for applications and extensions to various markets, such as goods, services, financial and labor markets, etc., in economy.

Macroeconomic model: This paper is a foundation stone for developing a macroeconomic model for business cycles by interconnection of n number of markets for n commodities in economy.

Acknowledgements

We gratefully acknowledge the helpful comments and suggestions provided by Richard G. Anderson (Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis), Valentin Verdier (Michigan State University) and Wilfred Dolfsma (University of Groningen).

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest regarding the publication of this paper.

References

[1] Ackerman, F., Nadal, A., & Gallagher, K. P. (2004). The Flawed Foundations of General Equilibrium Theory: Critical Essays on Economic Theory. Routledge.
https://doi.org/10.4324/9780203799963
[2] Akerlof, G. A. (1970). The Market for “Lemons”: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84, 488-500.
https://doi.org/10.2307/1879431
[3] Angeletos, G.-M., & Calvet, L.-E. (2005). Incomplete-Market Dynamics in a Neoclassical Production Economy. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 41, 407-438.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmateco.2004.09.005
[4] Arrow, K. J. et al. (1952). An Extension of the Basic Theorems of Classical Welfare Economics. Cowles Commission for Research in Economics, The University of Chicago.
[5] Arrow, K. J., & Debreu, G. (1954). Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 22, 265-290.
https://doi.org/10.2307/1907353
[6] Bator, F. M. (1958). The Anatomy of Market Failure. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 72, 351-379.
https://doi.org/10.2307/1882231
[7] Bertola, G., & Caballero, R. J. (1990). Kinked Adjustment Costs and Aggregate Dynamics. In M. Eichenbaum, E. Hurst, & J. A. Parker (Eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1990 (Vol. 5, pp. 237-296). MIT Press.
https://doi.org/10.1086/654143
[8] Chen, H. A., Levy, D., Ray, S., & Bergen, M. (2008). Asymmetric Price Adjustment in the Small. Journal of Monetary Economics, 55, 728-737.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2008.05.002
[9] Chen, W., Feng, Q., & Seshadri, S. (2014). Inventory-Based Dynamic Pricing with Costly Price Adjustment. Production and Operations Management, 24, 732-749.
https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2479011
[10] D’Arge, R., & Hunt, E. K. (1971). Environmental Pollution, Externalities, and Conventional Economic Wisdom: A Critique. Boston College Environmental Affairs Law Review, 1, 266-286.
[11] Danziger, L. (1999). A Dynamic Economy with Costly Price Adjustments. American Economic Review, 89, 878-901.
https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.89.4.878
[12] David, P. A. (2007). Path Dependence: A Foundational Concept for Historical Social Science. Cliometrica, 1, 91-114.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-006-0005-x
[13] Debreu, G. (1959). Theory of Value: An Axiomatic Analysis of Economic Equilibrium. Number 17. Yale University Press.
[14] Diamond, P. A. (1971). A Model of Price Adjustment. Journal of Economic Theory, 3, 156-168.
https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531(71)90013-5
[15] Dolfsma, W. (2005). Towards a Dynamic (Schumpeterian) Welfare Economics. Research Policy, 34, 69-82.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2004.11.002
[16] Dolfsma, W., Finch, J., & McMaster, R. (2005). Market and Society: How Do They Relate, and How Do They Contribute to Welfare? Journal of Economic Issues, 39, 347-356.
https://doi.org/10.1080/00213624.2005.11506811
[17] Eden, B. (1981). Toward a Theory of Competitive Price Adjustment. The Review of Economic Studies, 48, 199-216.
https://doi.org/10.2307/2296880
[18] Folbre, N., & Nelson, J. A. (2000). For Love or Money—Or Both? The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14, 123-140.
https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.14.4.123
[19] Frey, B. S., & Oberholzer-Gee, F. (1997). The Cost of Price Incentives: An Empirical Analysis of Motivation Crowding-Out. The American Economic Review, 87, 746-755.
[20] George, D. (2004). Preference Pollution: How Markets Create the Desires We Dislike. University of Michigan Press.
[21] Green, J. (1977). The Non-Existence of Informational Equilibria. The Review of Economic Studies, 44, 451-463.
https://doi.org/10.2307/2296901
[22] Greenwald, B. C., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1986). Externalities in Economies with Imperfect Information and Incomplete Markets. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101, 229-264.
https://doi.org/10.2307/1891114
[23] Grossman, S. J., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1980). On the Impossibility of Informationally Efficient Markets. The American Economic Review, 70, 393-408.
[24] Hahn, F. (1984). Equilibrium and Macroeconomics. Blackwell Oxford.
[25] Hemsley-Brown, J. (2011). Market Heal Thyself: The Challenges of a Free Market in Higher Education. Journal of Marketing for Higher Education, 21, 115-132.
https://doi.org/10.1080/08841241.2011.623832
[26] Herings, P. J.-J. (1996). A Globally and Universally Stable Price Adjustment Process. In Static and Dynamic Aspects of General Disequilibrium Theory (Vol. 13, pp. 349-388). Springer.
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4615-6251-1_10
[27] Howell, D. R. (2004). Fighting Unemployment: The Limits of Free Market Orthodoxy. Oxford University Press.
https://doi.org/10.1093/0195165845.001.0001
[28] Kaldor, N. (1972). The Irrelevance of Equilibrium Economics. The Economic Journal, 82, 1237-1255.
https://doi.org/10.2307/2231304
[29] Lucas, R. E. (1967). Adjustment Costs and the Theory of Supply. The Journal of Political Economy, 75, 321-334.
https://doi.org/10.1086/259289
[30] Maćkowiak, B. A., & Wiederholt, M. (2011). Business Cycle Dynamics under Rational Inattention. ECB Working Paper No. 1331, European Central Bank.
https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1804852
[31] Maćkowiak, B., & Wiederholt, M. (2009). Optimal Sticky Prices under Rational Inattention. The American Economic Review, 99, 769-803.
https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.99.3.769
[32] Nawaz, N. (2017). An Optimal Quantity Tax Path in a Dynamic Setting. European Journal of Government and Economics, 6, 191-225.
https://doi.org/10.17979/ejge.2017.6.2.4329
[33] Nawaz, N. (2019a). A Dynamic Model for an Optimal Specific Import Tariff. The International Trade Journal, 33, 255-276.
https://doi.org/10.1080/08853908.2018.1544102
[34] Nawaz, N. (2019b). Dynamics of Economic Efficiency in Tariff and Trade. Australian Economic Papers, 58, 416-443.
https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-8454.12162
[35] Nawaz, N. (2020). Converting Remittances to Investment: A Dynamic Optimal Policy. Journal of Economics and Finance, 44, 140-160.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s12197-019-09473-9
[36] Nawaz, N. (2021). Efficiency on the Dynamic Adjustment Path in a fiNancial Market. Journal of Economics and Finance, 45, 49-74.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s12197-020-09523-7
[37] Nawaz, N. (2022). A Dynamic Optimal Trade Facilitation Policy. The International Trade Journal, 36, 102-122.
https://doi.org/10.1080/08853908.2020.1859021
[38] Nerlove, M. (1958). Adaptive Expectations and Cobweb Phenomena. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 72, 227-240.
https://doi.org/10.2307/1880597
[39] Oakley, A., Ashton, J. et al. (1997). The Gift Relationship: From Human Blood to Social Policy. London School of Economics and Political Science (LSE).
[40] Satz, D. (2010). Why Some Things Should Not Be for Sale: The Moral Limits of Markets. Oxford University Press.
https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780195311594.001.0001
[41] Sen, A. (1993). Markets and Freedoms: Achievements and LImitations of the Market Mechanism in Promoting Individual Freedoms. Oxford Economic Papers, 45, 519-541.
https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordjournals.oep.a042106
[42] Stiglitz, J. E. (1991). The Invisible Hand and Modern Welfare Economics. Technical Report, National Bureau of Economic Research.
https://doi.org/10.3386/w3641
[43] Sunstein, C. R. (1999). Free Markets and Social Justice. Oxford University Press.
[44] Talman, A., & Thijssen, J. (2006). Existence of Equilibrium and Price Adjustments in a Finance Economy with Incomplete Markets. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 42, 255-268.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmateco.2005.02.002
[45] Tuinstra, J. (2004). A Price Adjustment Process in a Model of Monopolistic Competition. International Game Theory Review, 6, 417-442.
https://doi.org/10.1142/S0219198904000289
[46] Wright, R. (1986). Job Search and Cyclical Unemployment. The Journal of Political Economy, 94, 38-55.
https://doi.org/10.1086/261362

Copyright © 2024 by authors and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

Creative Commons License

This work and the related PDF file are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.