Do Religious Freedom vis-a-vis Trade Openness Affect Economic Growth? A Cross-Country Empirical Investigation

Abstract

Does religious freedom steer economic growth impact of trade-openness? This paper employs the method of moments-quantile regression to panel data of 117 developed and developing countries to show that countries that accommodate greater liberal religious beliefs enjoy, on average, higher growth in per capita income via deeper trade openness. Empirical results reveal that the dynamic nexus between trade and economic growth across developing countries is subject to the institutional environment. Therefore, results indicate that trade openness favours economic growth when institutional quality improves.

Share and Cite:

Behera, S. , Mishra, T. and Dash, D. (2023) Do Religious Freedom vis-a-vis Trade Openness Affect Economic Growth? A Cross-Country Empirical Investigation. Theoretical Economics Letters, 13, 119-137. doi: 10.4236/tel.2023.131007.

1. Introduction

An extant body of literature covering both intra- and inter-country settings has shown that trade openness tends to accelerate economic growth (see, among others, Yanikkaya, 2003; Manole & Spatareanu, 2010 ). While various socioeconomic and political determinants have been shown to moderate the dynamic long-term effects of openness on growth, countries’ affine nature in religiosity could be a potential driver of growth and openness relationships. In particular, one may ask, does the persistence of certain types of religious beliefs shape growth and trade-openness relationships? In earlier work, Barro and McCleary (2003) and Durlauf et al. (2012) have explored the macroeconomic effects of religious beliefs on aggregate economic outcomes. Moreover, Barro and McCleary (2003) have identified the two dimensions of religion, i.e., religious beliefs and participation in religious activities. The key findings from their study indicate that some aspects of religious beliefs positively correlated with economic growth, while religious activities measured through participation in church attendance negatively correlated with economic growth. Besides, they also suggest that higher levels of church attendance depress economic growth because attendance in the church could use a larger share of resources by the religious sector, while fewer resources could be used for the primary output sector. Therefore, they find a reverse relationship between religious belief and economic growth, indicating that less attendance in church generates more output and facilitates the economy to grow faster.

Previous literature examined the relationship between religious affiliations and economic growth in the context of economic growth determinants. For instance, Fernandez et al. (2001) find that Confucianism is one of the most determinants of economic growth. Moreover, they find that any historical or cultural explanations which are not necessarily related to religion have a heterogeneous impact on growth experiences. Nevertheless, Barro and McCleary’s (2003) findings that religion matters for economic growth are an important insight which lies outside the domain of the canonical neoclassical model. Several scholars have given importance to various parameters for economic growth. The well-known works in this line of thought include Sachs (2003) , finding that economic growth and other economic and demographic dimensions strongly correlate with geographical and ecological variables. Other prominent scholars also explain several valuable factors in cross-country differences, including Institutions (Acemoglu et al., 2001, 2002; Acemoglu & Johnson, 2005) and ethnic heterogeneity (Easterly & Levine, 1997; Alesina et al., 2003) . The neoclassical models explained by several prominent scholars prove that religion has a specific role in economic growth, which represents the beginning of a new research direction in international economics, incorporating the growth models.

Nevertheless, in a related work focusing on nations’ cultural characteristics, Inglehart and Baker (2000) and Deneulin and Rakodi (2011) argue that nations’ culture determines the movement of economic growth. However, in these and similar studies, a cultural dimension is envisaged in the form of honesty and work ethics, among others. Religion is one of the critical dimensions of a country’s culture. This can influence the extent of “trade dynamics” by controlling the type of import and export (reflecting religion-driven taste and preferences). Therefore, this paper investigates religion’s role in the growth and trade-openness relationship. North (1990) argues that informal institutions’ religious freedom, customs, ideology, and code of conduct have essential growth consequences in earlier work.

Similarly, previous studies like Woodberry (2012) argue that religious freedom, like modernity, has played a significant role in developing financial and political institutions leading to changes in growth dynamics in a country. More recently, the empirical work by Rasoanomenjanahary et al. (2022) finds that trade openness has an adverse effect on economic growth in Madagascar. Similarly, Oppong-Baah et al. (2022) find that trade openness and the real exchange rate substantially affect economic growth in Ghana and Nigeria. Further, Mallick and Behera (2020) find evidence of asymmetric cointegration between economic growth and trade openness in India during the pre-trade reforms period 1960-1990 and the post-trade reforms period 1991-2018. Goldar et al. (2020) examine the impact of trade liberalization in India during the late 1990s and 2000s on the productivity of manufacturing firms and find that the lowering of output tariff had a more significant impact on the productivity of Indian manufacturing firms than the lowering of tariff on intermediate inputs. Further, Behera (2014) found that after trade liberalisation in India, industries which experienced a decline in the tariff cost exhibited more substantial growth in domestic firms’ productivity.

In our work, we ask a broad question: does religious freedom (have a heterogeneous) effect on economic growth and the trade-openness relationship? We contribute to the literature on economic growth and trade-openness literature by investigating the instrumental role of religious freedom. To explore the religious freedom heterogeneous impact on trade openness-economic growth nexus, we have selected panel data covering 117 countries consisting of developed and developing economies. Besides, following the World Development Indicators database of the World Bank and based on World Bank gross national income (GNI) per capita in current USD, our sample of 117 countries comprises high-income, upper-middle-income, and lower-middle-income countries. A robust empirical assessment of panel data covering 117 countries (comprising high-income, upper-middle-income, and lower-middle-income countries) reveals that religious freedom (like less liberal, moderate liberal, and high liberal) has a significant effect on economic growth-trade openness interdependence. However, the impact of religious freedom on the dynamic nexus between economic growth and trade openness is heterogeneous.1

Figures 1-4 portray the relationship between religious freedom and economic growth (GDP per capita) across different groups of countries through a scatter-fitted line. Figure 1 explains the relationship between religious freedom and economic growth in the case of a full panel of 117 countries consisting of developed and developing economies. It seems that the relationship between religious freedom and economic growth is positive (see Figure 1). Besides, the fitted line is not highly positive, indicating that highly liberal religious beliefs and practices have a specific impact on economic growth. However, the impact of religious

Figure 1. Religious freedom and GDP per capita, full-panel.

Figure 2. Religious freedom and GDP per capita, highly-liberal.

Figure 3. Religious freedom and GDP per capita, moderate-liberal.

Figure 4. Religious freedom and GDP per-capita, less-liberal.

freedom on economic growth is not substantially more decisive in the case of highly liberal groups of countries (see Figure 1).

Similarly, Figure 2 explains the relationship between religious freedom and economic growth in the case of highly liberal religious groups of countries. The fitted line between freedom of religious faith and practices and countries’ economic growth reveals a positive and upward movement relationship. Therefore, it shows that religious freedom significantly raises economic growth across groups of highly liberal religious countries. Nevertheless, the impact of religious beliefs, faith and practices on economic growth in other groups of countries is contrary to the previously fitted line and estimated results. Results reveal that the effects of religious belief and practices on economic growth are adverse in the case of moderate-liberal group countries (see Figure 3). In contrast, the impact of freedom of religious belief and practices on economic growth is relatively stagnant. Besides, the fitted line seems to be a horizontal straight line across countries with less liberal religious belief and practices (see Figure 4). Therefore, it is pretty inconclusive to arrive at a particular inference that freedom to religious belief and practices has any significant impact on economic growth across the countries with less liberal in religious practices and beliefs.

2. Empirical Construct and Estimation

2.1. Model

We follow prior literature and estimate a model that establishes interdependence between economic growth and trade openness (Equation (1)) (Yanikkaya, 2003; Manole & Spatareanu, 2010) .

G D P p c i t = α i + β 1 T R O P i t + β 2 I n s t i t + β 3 M a c i t + β k X i t k + ϵ i t (1)

where GDPpc is the per capita real GDP country i over a period t (t varies from 1990 to 2018). TROP represents trade openness; Inst is the institutional variable representing law and order, government policy, and countries’ stability. In the domain of institutional policies, we have taken autocratic (AR) and democratic regimes (DR) and religious freedom (RF) indexes. Mac indicates macroeconomic variables, including the market size (proxied by population (TP), human development index (HDI), macroeconomic price stability (proxied by the inflation rate, INFR), financial sector stability (proxied by external debt as a percentage of GDP, EXTD). The control variables (X) include social (SG) and political globalization (PG), financial globalization (FG), and countries’ economic uncertainty index (EUI). All variables come from databases like World Development Indicators, Penn World Table, United Nations Development Program, Polity IV, KOF Index, and Economic Uncertainty Institute.2

2.2. Estimation

Trade openness may not exert a unique effect on the entire distribution of economic growth; it is possible that a unit rise in the degree of openness can impact growth higher at the lower quantile (because economies facing persistence constraints can show higher promise of growth due to greater availability of opportunities through openness) than for countries at the higher quantile of growth (because of the elasticity of response of growth to a further re-openness of trade). While a mean-based estimate can paint an average picture of the relationship between growth and trade moderated by religious freedom, a median-based (or quantile) regression can unravel the differential magnitude of effects. Further, quantile regression allows unobserved heterogeneity, heterogeneous covariate effects, and some conditional heteroscedasticity in the model and is supposed to be more robust than mean-based regression, like least-squares estimation (Koenker, 2005; Lamarche, 2008) .

• The mean-based regression

In a typical least square approach, we specifically focus on estimating:

Q G D P p c i t ( τ | T R O P i t , I n s t i t , M a c i t , X i t ) = β 1 ( τ ) T R O P i t + β 2 ( τ ) I n s t i t + β 3 ( τ ) M a c i t + β k ( τ ) X i t + α i (2)

In the case of conventional mean-based like least squares regression, the parameters β 1 , β 2 , β 3 , and β k capture the average or mean response of economic growth due to small changes in trade openness, institutional and macroeconomic, and control variables. The main missing part of this kind mean based least squares regression is the possibility of a heterogeneous response of per-capita economic growth due to a change in trade openness and other variables. Therefore, it is inevitable that the average response of the dependent variable is less informative of the actual dynamics between the regressors and the full range of distribution of the dependent variable. The nature of economic growth is heterogeneous, and it is subject to a set of independent and control variables across countries. Therefore, it is true that the analysis focuses on the mean of the distribution that might miss important distributional effects of trade and democracy dynamics on economic growth across different countries. Taking into the aspect of tails of the distribution, we may uncover richer evidence. Therefore, we use quantile regression to capture this effect, which analyses the impact of trade, institutions, and macroeconomic factors on the entire distribution of countries’ economic growth. The nature of the data sets varies across cross-section means countries; over time, a panel data set for quantile regression would seem appropriate.

• Quantile estimation: panel regression

Lamarche (2008) , Geraci and Bottai (2007) have explained to the panel quantile regression estimator while controlling the individual-specific heterogeneity via fixed effects and exploring the impact of the heterogeneous covariates within the quantile regression models. The panel quantile regression framework that controls the individual-specific heterogeneity offers a more flexible approach than the classical Gaussian fixed and random effects estimators. Abrevaya and Dahl (2008) introduced an alternative approach to estimate quantile regression models for panel data while employing the correlated random-effects model of Chamberlain (1982) . After introducing the fixed effects in quantile regression, the specification is written as follows:

Q G D P p c i t ( τ | T R O P i t , I n s t i t , M a c i t , X i t ) = β 1 ( τ ) T R O P i t + β 2 ( τ ) I n s t i t + β 3 ( τ ) M a c i t + β k ( τ ) X i t + α i (3)

The parameter β ( τ ) captures the effect of exogenous variables at the τ-th quantile of the conditional distribution of countries’ economic growth. This model can be estimated by solving the following minimization problem,

min β α i = 1 N t = 1 T ρ τ ( G D P p c i t β 1 ( τ ) T R O P i t β 2 ( τ ) I n s t i t β 3 ( τ ) M a c i t β k ( τ ) X i t α i ) (4)

where ρ τ is the standard quantile regression check function (e.g., Koenker & Bassett, 1978; Koenker, 2005 ).

• Endogeneity issues

There are possible endogenous explanatory variables and endogeneity problems in the empirical estimation. Certain explanatory variables like institutional, macroeconomic, and control variables are correlated. The types of simultaneity bias are observed by the reverse causality of economic growth per capita and macroeconomic and institutional variables. At the same time, a rise in macroeconomics, financial stability and stable institutional policy can create a positive externality for the country’s economic growth. Nevertheless, other types of endogeneity problems arise from the omitted variable bias. The inclusion of policy-oriented variables like institutional variables helps ameliorates the problem of endogeneity of GDP. However, it is still entirely plausible that variables like culture or geographic factors play a specific role in the economic growth-trade dynamics relationship. Therefore, to mitigate these types of endogeneity issues in the models, this study has applied a recent estimation procedure, the Method of Moments-Quantile Regression (MM-QR), to address the endogeneity issues and robustness check. The MM-QR estimates the structural quantile function defined by Chernozhukov and Hansen (2008) using the method of Machado and Silva (2019) .3

3. Results

Descriptive statistics are presented in Table 1. Table 2 shows quantile regression results for the total sample and sub-samples based on religious freedom (less liberal, moderate liberal, and high liberal). We find that the signs and magnitudes of the coefficients of trade openness vary across quantiles. This suggests that higher openness does not necessarily facilitate higher economic growth. More specifically, in the case of a full sample of 117 countries, the estimated coefficients of trade openness are negative and significantly different from zero at the 75th and 90th quantiles (see Columns 1 and 2, Table 2). This suggests that trade openness significantly dampens economic growth in mixed groups of countries, including developed and developing countries. Therefore, results exhibit that trade share as a percentage of GDP (representing trade openness) in certain circumstances during the phase of low financial development and macroeconomic instability dampens the economic growth of developing countries.

Table 1. Descriptive statistics.

Notes: HDI, RF, and EUI score varies from 0 to 1. AR and DR score ranges from 0 to 10. PG, SG, TG, and FG score ranges from 0 to 100. *** indicates significance at a 1% level.

Table 2. Quantile regression (QR) results.

Notes: Standard error in brackets. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

Further, the results of other groups of countries following the religious freedom index are quite contrary, and the empirical consequences are inconclusive. Moreover, results exhibit that trade openness significantly enhances economic growth across the less-liberal and moderate-liberal religious beliefs countries. In contrast, empirical results demonstrate that at 90th quantiles, trade openness significantly dampens economic growth across high-liberal religious beliefs and practices groups countries (see Column 8, Table 2). This suggests that high-liberal in religious beliefs and practices does not facilitate economic growth. This is consistent with the findings of Barro and McCleary (2003) , indicating that high-liberal religious beliefs and practices and more extensive participation in church during working hours sometimes become impractical use of public resources, which harms the country’s production and economic growth.

The effects of democratic regimes across most countries are negative and significantly different from zero. However, the coefficients of autocratic regimes in highly liberal religious belief countries are positive and significantly different from zero. This suggests that countries with highly liberal religious beliefs with a highly authoritarian system have higher economic growth.

Notwithstanding, religious belief plays a vital role in economic growth in highly liberal countries. However, religious freedom negatively affects the economic growth of moderately liberal countries. We then account for macroeconomic and specific control variables’ effects on economic growth across different countries. Results reveal that social and political globalization substantially affects the economic growth of the sets of different countries. Further, results indicate that, like social openness, financial globalization is a relevant driver of economic growth across different sub-sets of religious openness countries. Figures 5-7 portray the quantile plot of explanatory variables’ effect on economic growth in groups like less, moderate and high-liberal countries. In the case of less-liberal groups of countries, Figure 5 portrays that the quantile plot of the total population, social globalization, autocratic regimes, and religious freedom positively impact economic growth. The trade openness’s impact on economic growth is pretty downward, which shows a declining trend at an early stage and later, its impact on economic growth is positive. The quantile plot shows economic policy uncertainty and external debt (% GDP), indicating that the financial stability parameters are swinging upwards and downwards, and fluctuating trends and these effects on economic growth fluctuate. In comparison, the quantile plot shows that political globalization and the rate of inflation adversely affect economic growth in the less-liberal religious freedom countries.

Nevertheless, Figure 6 portrays that the effect of HDI, autocratic regimes and religious freedom on economic growth seems negative across moderate-liberal groups in religious beliefs and practices countries. However, the quantile plot shows that the effect of trade openness on economic growth seems positive and has upward trends. This is consistent with the empirical evidence obtained from the quantile regression results. Besides, the quantile plot shows the impact of economic policy uncertainty, social and financial globalization, total population (indicating the market size of a country), and inflation rate oscillating. This suggests that macroeconomic price instability, abrupt changes and uncertainty in

Figure 5. The effects of explanatory variables upon economic growth (less liberal).

Figure 6. The effects of explanatory variables upon economic growth (moderate-liberal).

Figure 7. The effects of explanatory variables upon economic growth (high-liberal).

economic policy adversely affect economic growth. This is possible because many emerging markets and developed countries passed through the phase of global financial shocks, oil price shocks, and the east Asian financial crisis during the 1990s and after the 2000s. As the financial markets are interrelated, and to overcome these shocks and to revamp the economy from these shocks, policy planners of many countries have taken unstable policies. Therefore, erratic changes in the economics and financial policies and macroeconomic price instability facilitated an adverse effect on economic growth.

Figure 7 indicates that the quantile plot of trade openness shows a declining and rising trend during the study period. However, the quantile plot of religious freedom, democratic regimes, social and financial globalization, and the inflation rate seems to be declining. This indicates that a high and consistent inflation rate dampens economic growth across high-liberal countries. In contrast, economic policy uncertainty’s effect on economic growth fluctuates. However, it appears to be a positive impact on economic growth across the groups of highly liberal religious beliefs and practices countries. Although the quantile plot shows decreasing trend at an early period, after a certain period, the trend shows rising, indicating that economic policy uncertainty even positively affects economic growth.

Across quantiles and for all countries, financial sector stability measured by the external debt coefficients is negative and significantly different from zero. Therefore, this result complies with the argument that greater financial instability would decrease countries’ economic growth. Alternatively, as we discussed before, we re-estimate the empirical model using the MM-QR technique to avoid endogeneity bias. The MM-QR estimated results are reported in Table 3. The trade openness variable remains negative and significant in highly liberal means

Table 3. MM-QR results.

Notes: Standard error in brackets. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

high openness religious belief groups of countries. This confirms our previous findings that high liberal religious belief does not necessarily facilitate the countries’ economic growth. Instead, results demonstrate that other institutional and macroeconomic variables like autocratic regimes and social and financial globalization substantially affect countries’ economic growth. Our results provide considerable evidence for the hypothesis that countries with highly liberal religious beliefs can promote growth, which goes beyond the existing findings on the association between economic growth and trade policy.

Further, results reveal that economic uncertainty across countries adversely affects the economic growth of various countries. This suggests that countries with a high volatility of uncertainty in democratic regimes and high economic uncertainty reversely affect economic growth. Nevertheless, external effects like expenditure on human capital, an essential element in the growth of knowledge and skills of the labour, argued that the population with human capital has a similar role in enhancing economic growth. Hence, we can say that HDI promotes growth through higher trade flows.

4. Conclusion

This study attempts to differentiate the heterogeneous role of trade openness in growth acceleration among countries under various categories of religious freedom. Further, by introducing a political set-up (democratic-autocratic governance) within our model alongside religious freedom, we conclude that countries endowed with high liberals in religious belief experience more significant growth in income per capita. Our results are robust in accounting for institutional, macroeconomic, and specific control variables and correcting possible endogeneity in estimation. Further, improved social openness, increased human development, and increased religious tolerance could accelerate economic growth. Empirical results reveal that the relationship between openness to trade and economic growth across developing countries is subject to the institutional environment.

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank anonymous journal reviewers for their valuable comments and insightful suggestions, which enabled us to improve the quality of this paper to a large extent. We would also like to thank the Editors and Joy Deng, Managing Editor of the journal, for giving us a chance to revise this paper.

Appendix

Table A1. Classification of countries based on RF.

Table A2. Description of variables and sources of the data.

Figure A1. Hanging rootogram for quantile regression (less liberal).

Figure A2. Hanging rootogram for quantile regression (moderate-liberal).

Figure A3. Hanging rootogram for quantile regression (high-liberal).

NOTES

1Note that we have further subdivided the total sample of 117 countries based on the religious freedom (RF) index (0 < RF < 1). The religious freedom (RF) data are collected from the familiar GovData360 database of the World Bank. We consider that countries with RF ≤ 0.5, 0.5 ≤ RF ≤ 0.75, and RF ≥ 0.75 are less liberal, moderately liberal and highly liberal countries (see Table A1, Appendix).

2See Table A2, Appendix for detailed discussion of variables definition and sources of the data.

3For detailed estimation procedure of MM-QR estimator, see Machado and Silva (2019) .

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest regarding the publication of this paper.

References

[1] Abrevaya, J., & Dahl, C. M. (2008). The Effects of Birth Inputs on Birthweight: Evidence from Quantile Estimation on Panel Data. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 26, 379-397.
https://doi.org/10.1198/073500107000000269
[2] Acemoglu, D., & Johnson, S. (2005). Unbundling Institutions. Journal of Political Economy, 113, 949-995.
https://doi.org/10.1086/432166
[3] Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation. American Economic Review, 91, 1369-1401.
https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.91.5.1369
[4] Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2002). Reversal of Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribution. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 1231-1294.
https://doi.org/10.1162/003355302320935025
[5] Alesina, A., Devleeschauwer, A., Easterly, W., Kurlat, S., & Wacziarg, R. (2003). Fractionalization. Journal of Economic Growth, 8, 155-194.
https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1024471506938
[6] Barro, R. J., & McCleary, R. M. (2003). Religion and Economic Growth across Countries. American Sociological Review, 68, 760-781.
https://doi.org/10.2307/1519761
[7] Behera, S. R. (2014). Local Firms Productivity Spillover from Foreign Direct Investment: A Study of Indian Manufacturing Industries. International Journal of Technological Learning, Innovation and Development, 7, 167-190.
https://doi.org/10.1504/IJTLID.2014.065883
[8] Chamberlain, G. (1982). Multivariate Regression Models for Panel Data. Journal of Econometrics, 18, 5-46.
https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(82)90094-X
[9] Chernozhukov, V., & Hansen, C. (2008). Instrumental Variable Quantile Regression: A Robust Inference Approach. Journal of Econometrics, 142, 379-398.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2007.06.005
[10] Deneulin, S., & Rakodi, C. (2011). Revisiting Religion: Development Studies Thirty Years On. World Development, 39, 45-54.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2010.05.007
[11] Durlauf, S. N., Kourtellos, A., & Tan, C. M. (2012). Is God in the Details? A Re-Examination of the Role of Religion in Economic Growth. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 27, 1059-1075.
https://doi.org/10.1002/jae.1245
[12] Easterly, W., & Levine, R. (1997). Africa’s Growth Tragedy: Policies and Ethnic Divisions. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 1203-1250.
https://doi.org/10.1162/003355300555466
[13] Fernandez, C., Ley, E., & Steel, M. F. (2001). Model Uncertainty in Cross-Country Growth Regressions. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 16, 563-576.
https://doi.org/10.1002/jae.623
[14] Geraci, M., & Bottai, M. (2007). Quantile Regression for Longitudinal Data Using the Asymmetric Laplace Distribution. Biostatistics, 8, 140-154.
https://doi.org/10.1093/biostatistics/kxj039
[15] Goldar, B., Chawla, I., & Behera, S. R. (2020). Trade Liberalization and Productivity of Indian Manufacturing Firms. Indian Growth and Development Review, 13, 73-98.
https://doi.org/10.1108/IGDR-10-2018-0108
[16] Inglehart, R., & Baker, W. E. (2000). Modernization, Cultural Change, and the Persistence of Traditional Values. American Sociological Review, 65, 19-51.
https://doi.org/10.2307/2657288
[17] Koenker, R. (2005). Quantile Regression. Cambridge University Press.
https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511754098
[18] Koenker, R., & Bassett Jr., G. (1978). Regression Quantiles. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 46, 33-50.
https://doi.org/10.2307/1913643
[19] Lamarche, C. (2008). Private School Vouchers and Student Achievement: A Fixed-Effects Quantile Regression Evaluation. Labour Economics, 15, 575-590.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.labeco.2008.04.007
[20] Machado, J. A., & Silva, J. S. (2019). Quantiles via Moments. Journal of Econometrics, 213, 145-173.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2019.04.009
[21] Mallick, L., & Behera, S. R. (2020). Does Trade Openness Affect Economic Growth in India? Evidence from Threshold Cointegration with Asymmetric Adjustment. Cogent Economics & Finance, 8, Article ID: 1782659.
https://doi.org/10.1080/23322039.2020.1782659
[22] Manole, V., & Spatareanu, M. (2010). Trade Openness and Income—A Re-Examination. Economics Letters, 106, 1-3.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2009.06.021
[23] North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge University Press.
https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511808678
[24] Oppong-Baah, T., Bo, Y., Twi-Brempong, C., Amoah, E. O., Prempeh, N. A., & Addai, M. (2022). The Impact of Trade Openness on Economic Growth: The Case of Ghana and Nigeria. Journal of Human Resource and Sustainability Studies, 10, 142-160.
https://doi.org/10.4236/jhrss.2022.101010
[25] Rasoanomenjanahary, M. A., Cao, L., & Xi, Y. (2022). The Impact of Trade Openness on Economic Growth: Empirical Evidence from Madagascar. Modern Economy, 13, 629-650.
https://doi.org/10.4236/me.2022.135034
[26] Sachs, J. D. (2003). Institutions Don’t Rule: Direct Effects of Geography on per Capita Income.
https://doi.org/10.3386/w9490
[27] Woodberry, R. D. (2012). The Missionary Roots of Liberal Democracy. American Political Science Review, 106, 244-274.
https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055412000093
[28] Yanikkaya, H. (2003). Trade Openness and Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Empirical Investigation. Journal of Development Economics, 72, 57-89.
https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-3878(03)00068-3

Copyright © 2024 by authors and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

Creative Commons License

This work and the related PDF file are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.