Black-Scholes Model under G-Lévy Process

Abstract

In this paper, we study the option price theory of stochastic differential equations under G-Lévy process. By using G-Itô formula and G-expectation property, we give the proof of Black-Scholes equations (Integro-PDE) under G-Lévy process. Finally, we give the simulation of G-Lévy process and the explicit solution of Black-Scholes under G-Lévy process.

Share and Cite:

Xin, Y. and Zheng, H. (2021) Black-Scholes Model under G-Lévy Process. Journal of Applied Mathematics and Physics, 9, 3202-3210. doi: 10.4236/jamp.2021.912209.

1. Introduction

Nowadays, many studies are interested in stochastic differential equations (SDEs). And SDEs have been widely applied to economics and finance fields, such as option pricing in stock market see [1]. In the 1970s, Black and Scholes propose the famous option pricing model and promote the development of stocks, bonds, currencies, products. Subsequently, the famous Black-Scholes formula was paid more attention by many scholars. In 1976, Merton [2] proposed the logarithmic jump-diffusion models in stock price, which was described as a combination of Brownian motion and compound Poisson process.

Although option pricing formula has developed for a long time, there are many uncertainty problems in stock market. Many scholars have been studied the uncertainty problem. For example, Peng [3] [4] proposed the sublinear expectation space to solve the uncertainty problem. In particular, the G-expectation space plays an important role in solving them. Then the G-Brownian motion, G-Itô formula and G-center limit theorem are proposed for us in G-expectation framework. In this paper, we consider the following stock price S t such that:

d S t = a S t d t + b S t d W t + c S t d L t , t [ 0, T ] , (1)

where a is the interest rate, b is the volatility and c is the jump range of asset price, W t is a G-Brownian motion and L t is a G-Lévy process under the G-framework.

Yang and Zhao [5] introduce the simulation of G-Brownian and G-normal distribution under G-expectation and Chai studies the option pricing for stochastic differential equation under G-framework. Although G-Brownian motion solved many financial issues, some financial models that depend on the Lévy processes remain unresolved. Therefore, Peng and Hu [6] studied the G-Lévy process, which is the generalization of G-Brownian motion. And Krzysztof [7] introduced G-Itô formula and G-martingale representation for G-Lévy process.

In this paper, we study Black-Scholes model under G-Lévy process and prove the Integro-PDE by using G-Itô formula, option pricing formula and G-expectation property. Then we simulate the G-Lévy process and the stock price S t by using the new algorithms. Meanwhile, we give a numerical example to verify the result of simulation.

We introduce some notation as follows:

C b k ( q ) : the space of functions φ : x q with uniformly bounded partial derivatives x k 1 φ for 1 k 1 k .

C: a generic constant depending only on the upper bounds of derivatives of a , b , c and h, and C can be different from line to line.

The outline of the paper is as follows. In Section 2, we introduce some necessary notations and theorems, such as the G-Lévy process and G-Itô formula. In Section 3, we propose a new theorem that gives the proof of Black-Scholes equations (Integro-PDE) under G-Lévy process. Finally, some numerical simulations for G-Lévy process and stock price are given in Section 4.

2. Preliminaries

In this section, we will introduce some basic knowledge and notation that is the focus of this paper. Throughout this paper, we will give the definition of G-Lévy process. Unless otherwise specified, we use the following notations. Let

| x | = x , x 1 2 be the Euclidean norm in q and x , y is the scalar product of x , y . If A is a vector or matrix, its transpose is denoted by AT. Next, we will give the definition of Sublinear expectation and G-Lévy process.

Definition 1. [6] (Sublinear expectation) Let is a linear space and X 1 , X 2 , we give the definition of sublinear expectation E :

● monotonicity: E [ X 1 ] E [ X 2 ] for X 1 X 2 .

● constant preserving: E [ c ] = c with c .

● sub-additivity: E [ X 1 + X 2 ] E [ X 1 ] + E [ X 2 ] .

● positive homogeneity: E [ λ X 1 ] = λ E [ X 1 ] for λ 0 .

Therefore, we call the triple ( Ω , , E ) a sublinear expectation space.

Definition 2. [6] (G-Lévy process) Assume X = ( X s ) s 0 is a Lévy process, X s f is a generalized G-Brownian motion and X s g is of finite variation. We say the X is a G-Lévy process if satisfy the following conditions:

● for s 0 , there exists a Lévy process ( X s f , X s g ) satisfies X s = X s f + X s g .

● process X s f and X s g satisfy the following growth conditions:

lim s 0 E [ | X s f | 3 ] s 1 = 0 ; E [ | X s g | ] < C s for all s 0,

where C is a positive constant.

Lemma 1. [7] (G-Itô formula) For 1 i q , X t i is the k-th component of X t and it satisfies the following form:

X t i = X 0 i + 0 t a s i d s + j = 1 q 0 t b s i , j d W s j + 0 t E c ( e , s ) L ( d e , d s ) ,

where E q \ { 0 } , W s is a G-Brownian motion and L ( d e , d s ) is a G-Lévy process. For h C b 2 ( q ) , we deduce

h ( X t ) = h ( X 0 ) + i = 1 q 0 t a s i h ( X s ) x i d s + 1 2 i , k = 1 q j = 1 q 0 t b s i , j b s k , j 2 h ( X s ) x i x k d W s + i = 1 q j = 1 q 0 t b s i , j h ( X s ) x i d W s j + 0 t E [ h ( X s + c ( e , s ) ) h ( X s ) ] L ( d e , d s ) .

Lemma 2. [6] (Lévy-Khintchine representation) Assume X is a G-Lévy process in q , we have the following form

G X [ h ( ) ] : = l i m t 0 E [ h ( X t ) ] t 1 , (2)

where h C b 3 ( q ) . If Equation (2) is true, we have the following Lévy-Khintchine representation

G X [ h ( ) ] = sup ( λ , a , b ) U { D h ( 0 ) , a + 1 2 t r [ D 2 h ( 0 ) b b T ] + E h ( e ) λ ( d e ) } ,

where h ( 0 ) = 0 , E = q \ { 0 } , U V × q × , V is a set of all Borel measures of E and is a set of all positive definite symmetric matrix.

Lemma 3. [6] (Integro-PDE) Assume X is a G-Lévy process and the functions u = u ( x , t ) , and by using the Lemma 2 (Lévy-Khintchine representation), we have the following Integro-PDE:

u t sup ( λ , a , b ) U { D u , a + 1 2 t r [ D 2 u b b T ] + E ( u ( x + c ( e ) , t ) u ( x , t ) ) λ ( d e ) } = 0

where D 2 u is the Hessian matrix of u and a q , b q × q .

3. Black-Scholes Equations under G-Lévy Process

In this section, we will give the Black-Scholes equations under G-Lévy process, and prove the Integro-PDE by combining the G-Itô formula and the option pricing formula.

Theorem 1. (Black-Scholes equations) Assume u = u ( S t , t ) is the option price and S t is the stock price. For Equation (1), we can obtain the following integral partial differential Equation (Integro-PDE) under G-Lévy process

u t + sup ( λ , a , b , c ) U { a S u S + b 2 S 2 2 2 u S 2 + ln ( 1 + c ) λ ( E ) S u S + ln 2 ( 1 + c ) λ ( E ) ( b 2 S 2 2 2 u S 2 + b 2 S 2 u S ) } a u = 0,

where a , b , c , U V × × × , V is a set of all Borel measures of E and λ ( E ) = E λ ( d e ) .

Proof. We define a uniform time partition on time interval [ 0, T ] and 0 = t 0 < t 1 < < t n < < t N = T , Δ t = t n + 1 t n for 0 n N . Let the function u ( S , t ) be sufficiently smooth, Δ W n = W t n + 1 W t n and Δ W n = W t n + 1 W t n . Using the G-Itô formula, we can obtain the explicit solution of Equation (1):

S t n + 1 = S a exp { a Δ t 1 2 b 2 Δ W n + b Δ W n + t n t n + 1 E [ ln ( 1 + c ) ] L ( d e , d s ) } . (3)

In the G-expectation space, we have the following product rule:

d W t d W t = d W t , d L t d L t = λ ( E ) d t + ( λ ( E ) d t ) 2 , d L t d t = 0, d W t d L t = 0.

Then, it is well known that the option pricing formula following form

u ( S a , t n ) = 1 r E ( [ u ( S t n + 1 , t n + 1 ) u ( S n , t n ) ] | S t n = S a ) + 1 r u ( S a , t n ) . (4)

Next, we introduce the Black-Scholes model under G-Lévy process. Using Taylor formula for u ( S t n + 1 , t n + 1 ) , we have

u ( S t n + 1 , t n + 1 ) u ( S a , t n ) = u ( S a , t n ) t Δ t + u ( S a , t n ) S ( S t n + 1 S a ) + 1 2 2 u ( S a , t n ) S 2 ( S t n + 1 S a ) 2 + O ( Δ t ) 3 2 . (5)

Substituting Equation (3) into (5), we obtain

u ( S t n + 1 , t n + 1 ) u ( S a , t n ) = u ( S a , t n ) t Δ t + u ( S a , t n ) S ( S a exp { X n } S a ) + 1 2 2 u ( S a , t n ) S 2 ( S a exp { X n } S a ) 2 + O ( Δ t ) 3 2 ,

where X n = a Δ t 1 2 b 2 Δ W n + b Δ W n + t n t n + 1 E ln ( 1 + c ) L ( d e , d s ) . Let λ ( E ) = E λ ( d e ) , it induces from Taylor expansion for exp { X n } that

u ( S t n + 1 , t n + 1 ) u ( S a , t n ) = [ u t + a S a u S ] Δ t S a b 2 2 u S Δ W n + S a ln ( 1 + c ) u S L E + S a b u S Δ W n + [ S a u S + S a 2 2 u S 2 ] 1 2 ( X n ) 2 + O ( Δ t ) 3 2 = [ u t + a S a u S ] Δ t S a b 2 2 u S Δ W n + S a ln ( 1 + c ) u S L E + S a b u S Δ W n + [ S a u S + S a 2 2 u S 2 ] 1 2 ( b 4 4 ( Δ W n ) 2 + b 2 ( Δ W n ) 2 b 3 Δ W n Δ W n + ln 2 ( 1 + c ) λ ( E ) Δ t + ln ( 1 + c ) λ ( E ) ( Δ t ) 2 ) + O ( Δ t ) 3 2 ,

where L E = t n t n + 1 E L ( d e , d s ) . Inserting the above result into Equation (4), we can deduce

u = 1 r E [ ( u t + a S a u S ) Δ t S a b 2 2 u S ( Δ W n ) + S a b u S ( Δ W n ) + S a ln ( 1 + c ) u S L E + [ S a u S + S a 2 2 u S 2 ] 1 2 ( b 4 4 ( Δ W n ) 2 + b 2 ( Δ W n ) 2 b 3 Δ W n Δ W n + ln 2 ( 1 + c ) λ ( E ) Δ t + O ( Δ t ) 3 2 ) | S t n = S a ] + 1 r u .

It induces from the G-expectation property and the fact u = u ( S t n , t n ) and Δ W n N ( 0 ; [ σ _ 2 Δ t , σ ¯ 2 Δ t ] ) that we can deduce

( 1 1 r ) u = Δ t r ( u t + sup ( λ , a , b , c ) U { a S a u S + ( b 2 S a 2 2 2 u S 2 ) + σ ¯ 2 ( b 2 S a 2 2 2 u S 2 ) σ _ 2 + ln ( 1 + c ) S a u S λ ( E ) + ln 2 ( 1 + c ) ( b 2 S 2 2 2 u S 2 + b 2 S 2 u S ) λ ( E ) } + O ( Δ t ) 1 2 ) ,

where r = 1 + a Δ t and a is risk-free rate. Consequently, we obtain the following integro-partial differential equation:

u t + sup ( λ , a , b , c ) U { a S u S + b 2 S 2 2 2 u S 2 + ln ( 1 + c ) λ ( E ) S u S + ln 2 ( 1 + c ) λ ( E ) ( b 2 S 2 2 2 u S 2 + b 2 S 2 u S ) } a u = 0.

The proof is completed. □

4. Numerical Experiment

In this section, we will give a numerical example for option pricing in stock market. And we study the stock price S t under G-Lévy process. Platen [1] introduces the application jump process in stock market of financial field. The simulation of G-Brown under G-framework see [5] [8] [9]. Next, we firstly study the simulation of Poisson jump process and G-Lévy process.

Algorithm 1. (The simulation of Poisson jump)

● Setting up the values of intensity λ and the terminal time T.

● Generating random number z i obeying exponential distribution with parameter lambda.

● Then by the formula t k = i = 1 k z i , we get the occurrence time t k ofn events.

● Plotting a ladder figure for the Poisson jump process.

Assume the intensity λ = 1.5 and the number of jumps are equal to 10. And Figure 1 shows that the simulation of Poisson jump process.

Figure 1. The plots of time and number of jumps for Poisson jump process.

Algorithm 2. (The simulation of G-Lévy process)

● Setting up the terminal time T and the intensity functions λ ( t ) , where λ ( t ) λ with λ is a constant.

● Generating the Poisson jump process random number with intensity λ and obtaining the time of occurrence s 1 , s 2 , , s n .

● Generating the uniformly distributed random number x i on ( 0,1 ) . If x 1 λ ( s i ) / λ , we retain the s i , else we give up the time s i .

● Plotting the time s i which are obtained in the above step and the number of jumps.

Suppose the intensity function λ ( t ) = t 5 and the number of jumps are equal to 25. For λ = 10 and λ = 15 , we simulate the G-Lévy process in Figure 2.

Next, we will introduce the Black-Scholes formula with jump under the G-Lévy process, and it is the generation of classical Black-Scholes formula. In [6], Peng and Hu use the option pricing formula under the G-Lévy process. There we will give the following examples.

Example 1. Consider the stock price S t has the following form:

d S t S t = a d t + b d W t + c d L t , t [ 0 , T ] , (6)

where the initial value S 0 = 0 , the interest rate a and volatility b are positive, W t is a G-brownian motion and L t is a G-Lévy process. Next, we give the explicit solution of Equation (6) on t [ 0 , 1 ]

S t = S 0 exp { a t 1 2 b 2 W t + b W t + 0 t E [ ln ( 1 + c ) ] L ( d e , d s ) } .

In this example, we firstly use three different coefficients a 1 = 0.1 , b 1 = 0.3 , c 1 = 0.1 , a 2 = 0.2 , b 2 = 0.2 , c 2 = 0.2 and a 3 = 0.3 , b 3 = 0.1 , c 3 = 0.3 to simulate the stock price S t . And the simulation of S t are given in Figure 3 with three different coefficients.

Because the interest rate a, volatility b and jump intensity c are variable, we study the influence of volatility b and jump intensity c on stock price S t . Let coefficients a = 0.1 , c = 0.1 , we plot the stock price S t with the time t under the different coefficients b = 0.1 , b = 0.2 , b = 0.3 in Figure 4. And we obtain the stock price S t will decrease with the increase of the volatility b.

Figure 2. The simulation of G-Lévy process.

Figure 3. The simulation of stock price S t with three different coefficients.

Figure 4. Stock price S t with three different coefficients b = 0.1 , b = 0.2 , b = 0.3 .

Figure 5. Stock price S t with different coefficients c = 0.5 , c = 1 , c = 5 .

Let coefficients a = 0.1 , b = 0.1 , we plot the stock price S t with the time t under the jump intensity coefficients c = 0.5 , c = 1 , c = 5 in Figure 5.

By comparing Figures 3-5, we obtain that coefficients a and b have a great influence on stock price S t than coefficient c. And the stock price S t has a small variety when coefficient c changes.

5. Conclusion

In this paper, by using G-Itô formula and G-expectation property, we prove the Integro-PDE under G-Lévy process. Then we study the influence of coefficients on stock price S t , and obtain the coefficients a , b that have a great influence on stock price S t . In the future, we will study the numerical scheme for solving the Integro-PDE. And the numerical scheme is important in financial field.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest regarding the publication of this paper.

References

[1] Platen, E. and Bruti-Liberati, N. (2010) Numerical Solution of Stochastic Differential Equations with Jumps in Finance. Springer Science, New York.
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-13694-8
[2] Merton, R. (1976) Option Pricing When Underlying Stock Returns Are Discontinuous. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 125-144.
https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(76)90022-2
[3] Peng, S. (2008) Multi-Dimensional G-Brownian Motion and Related Stochastic Calculus under G-Expectation. Stochastic Processes and Their Applications, 118, 2223-2253.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.spa.2007.10.015
[4] Peng, S. (2007) G-Expectation, G-Brownian Motion and Related Stochastic Calculus of Itô Type. In: Benth, F.E., Di Nunno, G., Lindstrøm, T., Øksendal, B. and Zhang, T., Eds., Stochastic Analysis and Applications, Abel Symposia, Vol. 2, Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg, 541-567.
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-70847-6_25
[5] Yang, J. and Zhao W. (2016) Numerical Simulations for G-Brownian Motion. Frontiers of Mathematics in China, 11, 1625-1643.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11464-016-0504-9
[6] Hu, M. and Peng, S. (2009) G-Lévy Processes under Sublinear Expectations.
[7] Krzysztof, P. (2012) Itô Calculus and Jump Diffusions for G-Lévy Processes.
[8] Chai, C. (2019) Application of G-Brown Motion in the Stock Price. Journal of Mathematical Finance, 10, 27-34.
https://doi.org/10.4236/jmf.2020.101003
[9] Neufeld, A. and Nutz, M. (2017) Nonlinear Lévy Processes and Their Characteristics. Transactions of the American Mathematical Society, 369, 69-95.
https://doi.org/10.1090/tran/6656

Copyright © 2024 by authors and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

Creative Commons License

This work and the related PDF file are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.