Scale Economies: An Economic Blessing? Should We Build Still Larger Ships?

Abstract

We represented shipping production using the Cobb-Douglas function: Q = A × Cα × Lb, which relates: 1) Capital, Labor and Production. 2) Indicates: Embodied technical progress; 3) the shares in production of Capital and Labor, and 4) the Scale Economies! We consciously digressed from “constant returns to scale”, and selected α + b > 1 for shipping industry and A = 1.07 due only to the higher speed of the vessel. We dealt also with the Marshallian artificial distinction of the economic periods in short and long. This we had to do it as the scale economies were related to long run, when capital (ships) is changeable. In shipping, we have the wrong idea that Capital and Labor quantities are fixed, and so isoquant lines are right angles. However, we accepted this as a working assumption, and also, we adopted complementarity between Capital and Labor. We showed also that shipping companies can be always in the long run! Shipping microeconomics is incomplete. The equilibrium of: 1) the vessel and 2) the shipping firm in the short and long run is missing. We attempted to provide these, as well industry’s equilibrium. Moreover, we showed the equilibrium… outside the equilibrium during a shipping depression and boom, when demand is either shorter or higher than optimal. We emphasized the technical efficiency of the vessels at shipbuilding stage, and then we introduced the iso-cost lines. Mathematically and diagrammatically, we identified the scale economies in maritime industry, where seaborne trade is the King. The typical bulk carrier from 34,000 average size in 1981 reached 81,284 dwt by 2011, judging by ships on order (2.4 times larger)! This paper revealed, however, that the Global financial Crisis in end-2008 curtailed scale economies! Two numerical examples used proved scale economies in maritime industry: the cost of building a 30,000 ship fell from $867 per dwt to $347 (for a 170,000 dwt), and the long run average total cost fell from $191 to $74… Also, for a 75,000-dwt tanker the long run average total cost fell from $13.08 to $6.72, for a ship 3 times larger. We found out also that ports “sabotage” scale economies in shipping as when the size of a tanker increased by 3 times, the port cost increased by 4 times! Our last warning was, however, that scale economies are a good thing, but they depend on the parcel size, and the other factors presented in the text, and in a final analysis they depend on appropriate, each time, individual demand (per vessel)! So, we may say to shipowners: build larger ships, if demand is there.

Share and Cite:

Goulielmos, A. (2021) Scale Economies: An Economic Blessing? Should We Build Still Larger Ships?. Modern Economy, 12, 1296-1319. doi: 10.4236/me.2021.128068.

1. Introduction

All along the establishment of economics, economists distinguished 3 types of returns to scale: constant, increasing and decreasing. Despite the fact that “increasing returns to scale” (Goulielmos, 2018a) are more interesting, economists for political reasons, stuck in the “constant returns to scale”. While traditional economists tried to accommodate returns to scale even since the time of Marshall (Pearce, 1992: p. 122) able contemporary economists discovered the “economies of scope1(Besanko et al., 2013: p. 63).

In shipping, we have 2 criteria of scale for companies: 1) the number of ships a company manages at a time, and 2) the number of tons of cargoes -liquid or dry which these ships can carry at about 95% of their dwt. This means that in shipping, ES can be recognized in 4 occasions: if a vessel gets larger, if a company gets larger, if the industry gets larger, and if ports become larger! (Graph 1)

Graph 1. Actions which provide ES in a maritime economy. Source: author.

As shown, the larger the size of a vessel or of a company, the higher the opportunity to gain scale economies. The larger the industry, meaning having more companies and vessels than hitherto, the more possible is to offer it a proper infrastructure. Ports and Canals are in fact partners and most scale economies in ships depend on Ports and Canals.

From the above criteria of size, the main is the number of tons (dw) a company manages. This indicates company’s carrying capacity, meaning the production capacity of vessels per voyage. This also reflects the availability of capital embodied in ships as the only and most important factor for their size and for its higher contribution in value vis-à-vis labor (crew). This is why shipping industry is called “capital-intensive” or the ratio Ct/Lt > 0 {1} in production (capital/labor ratio) (perhaps 5 to 1.5).

However, the production of ships is not static, as it does not take place in a specific location, as in other industries, but production places are determined by the tons of cargo that they have to be carried over, from origin to destination2. As a result, the ship production is both dynamic, subject to many factors, given that a number of independent firms contribute, or prevent, or create costs, and also may “steal” time from ship’s efficient and effective production! The ship manager has to manage and co-ordinate at least 5 - 10 other companies to complete effectively and efficiently vessel’s production3!

Apparently, time4 is a very strong factor of production in shipping (Goulielmos, 2018a), expressed in one objective of all companies: achieve a minimum off-hire time5 by companys vessels”. This is the maritime operational efficiency!

The production of ships, however, is even more complicated than in other companies. Ship’s production is determined by the distances that have to be covered, depending also on the speed of the particular vessel and on the time spent in ports. Moreover, as a ship loads and unloads cargo in ports, and crosses Canals, port efficiency and effectiveness, as well posts’ condition (congestion; ice; black-outs; rain, strikes etc.), affect the production of ships in time and cost. Ships when in ports do not produce, but they perform the “delivery” (of cargo within an agreed time).

Both ships and ports, as well canals6, have increased their efficiency over time-though Ports and Canals are followers in the sense that they make their work as faster7 as it can be, under normal circumstances, but following shipping developments. This can be recognized in what economists mean by external scale economies and embodied technical progress in ports and canals!

The value embodied in the cargo carried by ships may induce the owner of cargo to calculate the interest8 for the time the ship is crossing the sea and the time spent in port, till cargo can be bought to customers, and his/her money invested-in cargo is recouped. So, owners of cargo care about the duration (and safety) of the voyage, and appreciate the faster process, especially by companies which own containerships.

Moreover, the following distinction of ES (Graph 2), we believe, is very important.

As shown, scale economies are distinguished in money terms, and in physical terms. The analysis of scale economies in money terms is rather neglected though perhaps more or equally important, as we have done here. To most people scale economies coincide to the issue “when a fixed amount is divided over more units, like fixed cost.”

Monetary scale economies come when large shipping companies negotiate with the suppliers of oil to obtain lower prices (discounts in annual contracts). Efforts can also be paid with shipbuilders, agents, ship-repairers, suppliers of goods, and spare parts, of lubricants, of paints, of engines, with dry-dockers, etc. to get discounts.

A shipping company, as mentioned, is capital-intensive, and as a result its fixed cost is higher in the form of depreciation, administration cost and yield/profit sought after, etc. Fixed cost is the one paid independently of the level of production, and is subject to reductions by spreading it over a larger amount of units produced (in the form of a rectangular hyperbola). As argued elsewhere, fixed costs are a strategic variable, which cannot be managed in the short run after ships have been built or bought etc. (Goulielmos, 2021a).

As argued (Goulielmos, 2021a) a shipping company has to apply a strategy right from its establishment in having a portfolio of ships’ vintages in the middle

Graph 2. Types of scale economies in shipping industry. Source: author.

of the age pyramid, as lower vintages have higher operating costs and higher vintages have higher depreciation and yield amounts (=fixed cost)!

2. Paper’s Contribution

This paper tried to show, quantitatively, the existence of maritime technical progress, and if possible, to measure it in quantitative and in money terms. The tool was the famous Cobb-Douglas production function. First, we determined the value of α + β > 1 (increasing returns to scale) somehow intuitively and then we estimated A, i.e., the coefficient of technical progress, at 7%, while keeping Capital and sea Labor constant. The technical progress embodied in ships in money terms was reflected in lower freight rates by 8.2% less p.a. (1945-2021) due to competition! Additionally, we completed the microeconomic theory of the maritime company. Moreover, scale economies proved with numerical and diagrammatic means.

3. Aim and Organization of This Work

The paper aims at showing the impact that the size of the capital (ships) has on the production and cost of a shipping company. In fact, we aim at revealing the Scale Economies in shipping industry using data. This is the same, we believe, as to answer the questions: “Are shipping scale economies true? “And if so, how can a shipping firm achieve them?” Concurrently we will comment on the artificial separation of business life, made first by Marshall (1890), in short and long periods, showing that a shipping company, unlike its industry, is always in the long run, if it so wants!

Worth noting is that the paper moves within a competitive market (Graph 3).

As shown, the individual shipping company produces a fraction -made up by thousand-ton miles of the total production required by total demand, which is expressed in billion tons, and in equilibrium, AC should be equal to Price (MC = MR; equality of marginal cost to marginal revenue, and average cost). The AC curve indicates that a vessel cannot produce more than 95% of her capacity.

By Graph 3 we do not mean that Supply is not influenced by an individual company (like the “Sanko Co of Japan” in 1980s: see Stopford, 2009, p. 126; the “Eletson”) or by a group of companies (Oil companies in the past called seven sisters)!

Graph 3. A shipping company in a competitive market. Source: author.

The paper is organized in parts, after literature review. Part I dealt with Cobb-Douglas Production Function. Part II dealt with the short and long production periods. Part III dealt with completing the theory of shipping production, and showing firm’s and industry’s equilibria. Part IV dealt with the Scale Economies in Maritime Industry in practice. Part V provided an applied example of scale economies with data from tankers’ chartering. Finally, we conclude.

4. Literature Review

Worth noting is how a methodology applied by Marshall (1890) which moreover was not wanted, as he stated in the determination of prices of goods, to become a central tool in building a competitive advantage in Business Economics! Marshall (1920) mentioned the term “long period”, among other 3 ones, to indicate the time when a firm can make adjustment in its product price (Blaug, 1997: p. 682; 359-363).

Viner (1931) drew the long run average total cost (LR/ATC) curve of a firm, known as the envelope9 of all short-run average total cost (SR/ATC) ones! This means that a firm can easily and smoothly increase its scale, and by so doing reduce its long run average cost! Reality, however, is somehow more difficult. Marshall’s theory of the “short period” is by now very familiar, as most of it is found in modern textbooks and we will be brief on it.

Moreover, short run for a shipping company may cover a short time of its life a few… months. In fact, short run is a period, for a shipping company, we believe, when today is like yesterday, and tomorrow is like today. Everything we can, according to theory, is only to produce at t an amount ≥ or < than t − 1, or what we mean by “business as usual”.

Long run, however, is the period during which whatever had to change for the better, it has been changed (our definition). Thus, some companies will stay in the short run for ever, and others, the champions, will march into long run, we believe. But as we have argued elsewhere, many economic statements sound true, but they are deceptive. One of them is the “scale economies”, and the other is the extreme “division of labor” or perfect specialization.

Robinson (1965) stated the classical one of economists: in the “short-period, the stock of equipment is given” (p. 65), recognizing it as a convenient theoretical abstraction (p. 179). She also wrote that the “economies of the division of labor10” determine the minimum size of each type of a productive company (p. 69).

Of course, each entrepreneur, and a shipowner, is continually struggling to enlarge his/her business, and new firms are launched from time to time (Goulielmos, 2021b). Robinson (1965) argued that to increase the production (p. 336) from, or with, a single plant, this has certain limits, due also to the “specialization of the equipment”.

This last means that a firm is expected to concentrate its equipment (ships) to the production where it has a natural or acquired advantage… In shipping such advantage may come from the quality of crew, the quality of ships, or their special technical characteristics (e.g., double hull).

Such advantages, however, it may make company’s life easier, but shipping business life (=demand) allows and other companies to survive11, if the homogeneity12 property of services exists. Market prices are determined on the basis of the cost of the marginal producer (having the higher cost), if his/her production is needed. This is an important observation explaining why ships with high total cost continue to carry cargoes...

Above, in shipping, we determined the minimum staff, and the minimum size, of a (Greek) shipping company, we believe (excluding containerships; cruising and passenger ships). The above structure is the absolute necessary structure to carry-out operations, chartering, supply, port attendance, crewing, insurance, technical attendance, repairs, maintenance, accounting and MGA etc. and other office obligations in a tramp shipping company.

Tarski (1979) tried to present scale economies in transportation in very bad English. He found that the transport cost of oil by tankers from Persian Gulf to Japan in 1967, per ton, was falling from 16 shillings to 8.5 as the ship increased from 160,000 dwt to 600,000!

Stopford (2009: p. 75) admitted that ES played a major part in keeping sea transport costs low. For Stopford (p. 223) the relationship between cost and ship size defines ES. The total cost covers: operations, voyage, capital, cargo handling and maintenance (periodic). This has to be divided by ship’s dwt for one to arrive at average shipping cost.

Lorange (2009: p. 87-88) argued that a shipowner may have very similar assets, and it might pay to standardize his/her fleet. We may call it “the sister ships advantage”. Examples are the “General Maritime”, primarily owning Aframax and Suezmax tankers, i.e., almost similar designs, common spare parts, more standardized operations, common maintenance, etc. Also, “Seaspan” owning 23 identical (4250 TEU) containerships. Among Greeks, “Eletson Ltd Co” derived such benefits to the best of our knowledge.

Besanko et al. (2013; chapter 2) argued13 that few concepts in microeconomics are more fundamental to business strategy than … ES. By ES they mean the vehicle that one may use to obtain a cost advantage over its competitors!

This review has revealed a few important points. The first is that market allows companies with high average cost to be present in the market. The 2nd is that a shipping company is most of her life in the long run. The third is that the more scrapping is taking place, the more ships of larger sizes and lower ages, are replacing other ships, and the faster technical progress and scale economies emerge. The real pushing factor for technical progress is the new-buildings. Unfortunately, in 2021 we have the lowest level of such orders in the last 12 years!

The most valuable message of this review is that the lowest possible costs will determine firm’s success, and this can be done… by scale economies. Maritime economists present economies of scale (Stopford, 2009: p. 436) as granted, and just note that tankers increased from 17,000 dwt in 1950 to a VLCC in 1966 and a ULCC in 1976. In 1968 an 80,000-dwt tanker had cost about 27s in the pound/per ton (Rotterdam-Kuwait), while a 200,000-tanker had cost of about 18s or 34% saving (Stopford, 2009: p. 436). We did not stop to warn, however, that big ships need big cargoes!

5. Part I: A rich Production Function

Scale Economies exist if a reduction of the long run average cost (Total Cost/Qt), of the products (or services) produced (=output), is achieved. This can be done, by an increase in company’s production, Qt, due to a higher demand14, requiring a greater quantity of all factors of production.

Some inputs, as a result of the higher demand, and the additional time, stop to be fixed, as hitherto (e.g., capital equipment). ES mean quantitative (physical) savings. This does not exclude savings due to human element, par excellence pecuniary savings (see below), or other savings or economies, of course (e.g., of learning, of density etc.). In fact, economists have introduced quite a number of economies15 (this way… justifying their name)!

Scale reflects the quantities of all inputs used at one period in the production of a firm. ES are realizable, and do not occur automatically, like a “manna from heaven”. They are an excellent target for companies. ES are distinguished in internal and external.

Economists, since long ago, were “jealous” of Physicists and of Mathematicians, because latter’s sciences “allowed” them to be positive, precise, elegant and their theories could be subject to experiment! But economists must be prouder, we reckon, as their science is 1/2 based on Psychology (Goulielmos, 2018b, 2018c), and the other 1/2 on Economic Man’s Free Will (Priesmeyer, 1992)!

One tool of the mathematicians, which relates together 4 important economic concepts, Output, Capital, Labor and Technical Progress, is the “Cobb-Douglas production function”. This was first used by Wicksell (1851-1926) in 1901, and discovered independently by Cobb & Douglas (1928). Here we will use a generalized version of it by assuming

b 1 α or α + b > 1 , (1)

assuming increasing returns to scale. The returns to scale represent the rate at which Qt changes as the quantities of all inputs are varied.

Let a company’s output, Qt (=production)16, to be carried-out with the help of Capital, Ct and Labor Lt quantity:

Q t = A C α L b (2)

(an exponential equation), where α, b and A are constants (Eltis, 1966: p. 66), (Chiang & Wainwright, 2005: p. 386). In shipping industry, we expect, in the long run, the labor quantity to fall and the capital quantity to increase, in a ship newly built, for reasons explained below.

Example: let α = 1, and assume that the size of the vessel is doubled, from 60,000 to 120,000 dwt, meaning 2Ct, and labor (crew) to decrease by 10%, from 1Lt to 0.90Lt, and let b = 0.03. Then production Qt + 1 will be17 1.99 (rounded) times higher ... than before, assuming A = 1.

The constants α and b show the elasticity of production to Ct and Lt respectively, meaning the change in production due to a change in either Ct or Lt. They are called also distribution parameters meaning that they indicate the shares in the production of Ct and Lt. This is why certain economists prefer a + b = 1.

Did we arbitrarily assume that A is equal to 1? Yes… A in shipping must be higher than 1, given that between a vessel of 60,000 dwt and 120,000 dwt, embodied technical progress must have caused at least one knot higher speed! Thus

A = 1.07 . (3)

Then

Q t + 1 = 2.13 Q t (4)

(rounded) (=increasing returns to scale)!

Varian (1990: p. 302-303) argued that A measures the scale of production -roughly speaking when Ct = 1 and Lt = 1. This means

Q t + 1 = A × Q t × C t α × L t b and Q t + 1 = A × Q t , (5)

given Ct = 1 and Lt = 1. A may be considered as an efficiency parameter and indicator of the state of technology (Chiang & Wainwright, 2005).

Absolute important, we reckon, was to select α + b -in shipping- > 1! We selected also b = 0.03, assuming that a decrease in labor quantity (crew numbers) in essence leaves ship’s production intact18! This (α + b > 1) is a very important selection, as mentioned, as by this, we have excluded: all linearly homogeneous equations, constant returns to scale as well Eulers theorem!

In shipping, there were no attempts to estimate α or b. In estimates applied to US manufacturing, α found equal tο 0.25 (1899-1922 = 24 years), 0.10 and 0.50 (Douglas, 1948) and b equal to 0.75. Technical progress can be detected by function (3), meaning that technical progress is “embodied”. Cobb and Douglas (1928: p. 155) set A = 1.01. But they did not name A as a technical progress coefficient, but as standing for: “the quantitative effects of any force for which one has no quantitative data” and thus A stands as a catch-of-all the effects of such forces”.

Here we assumed A as showing the influence of speed only; but there exist and other factors like cranes, the ship’s design, etc., which increase the efficiency (time and production) of the vessel. But we have to exclude from A the distance effect, which has nothing to do with technology.

Moreover, Cobb and Douglas (1928) adopted constant returns to scale etc. by having: α + b = 1/4 + 3/4 = 1. To catch technical progress perhaps one needs long data (the sail-steam-oil transition e.g., took place gradually over certain centuries). In another paper we will try to estimate A for maritime economy.

6. Part II: Short and Long Runs

We saw that ES were related only to long-run! Because, in the short run, a firm is assumed not to change its fixed factors of production, apparently capital, which coincides with the criterion of scale in shipping, and needs time to be produced than to produce.

To put the above more correctly, and more generally: short run is the (calendar) time19 in which one factor of production, i.e., capital, cannot change (assumed fixed). The short-run distinction is also due to Marshall20 (1920) (Chap. V) (p. 313-5), (1890: 1st edition), who introduced it for the first time.

In shipping, theoretically, the number of ships in a firm in the short run cannot change, but not even labor (number of crew). This also means that neither the size of existing ships can change (by modification). The Capital/labor ratio is fixed, after the ship has been constructed. But (her production), i.e., the number of voyages per year, the sea distances covered, as well the speed of steaming applied, the bunkers consumed, the periodic maintenance carried-out, etc., all these costs and factors can vary in the short run.

Short run is the time one lives, and makes business! In the long run, as Keynes said, everybody is dead! Long-run is the time for company’s vision to be realized. Short run is the time to survive, so that to be round tomorrow. Short run is the bridge to long run. Shipping depressions destroy this bridge, and the passage cannot be made.

Short run is the fight time, and there, death can suddenly occur and a company has to be prepared to pass to long run, where time restrictions, limitations, obstacles, excuses etc. are removed… A short run after a short run brings a company to the long run. Life is a continuous function (in mathematical language), but business life is not, if company’s serious diseases are not cured in time. A successful short run allows a company to pass to long run, the same way life during one day leads to next day and all these today days lead to next year (i.e., to long run).

7. Part III: Our Theory of Shipping Production; Firms’ and Industry’s Equilibria

Economists have to cooperate, we reckon, with shipping Production Engineers, and shipbuilding mechanical engineers, because maritime economists require shipping production to be technically efficient first, so that to apply, next, economic conditions (i.e., the prices of inputs)!

Mathematics provided a production function in which, as we showed, two-usual suspects: variables/inputs, Capital Ct and labor Lt, are used to produce a third variable: output, Qt, (all variables > 0).

Shipbuilders may say that a single combination of Ct and Lt can be combined in a number of different ways, to produce different levels of Qt. Production function, however, pre-supposes technical efficiency, as mentioned. Qt is then the maximum obtainable one from every possible Ct and Lt combination. So, technical efficiency has to be prior, so that to apply the economic principles thereafter.

One advantage of the newly built ships is their technical efficiency, which relates them to a particular route. For used ships is no guarantee that they will serve the same route as that designed by their first owner. In practice, shipbuilders have standardized the types of ships for obvious reasons in 5 - 6 sizes (in Table 1) and taking into account canals’ dimensions, port sea drafts as well distances and the nature of cargo, the price of oil, speed’s level, fuel consumption, etc.

Shipping is a peculiar industry, because non-shipping economists consider the right-angle isoquants (Graph 4), as an extreme case, in which one factor cannot be substituted by the other (labor for capital, and vice versa). So, in shipping the 2 factors of production supposed to be are used in fixed proportions (Bilas, 1967: p. 59). Then the “elasticity of technical substitution” is zero. Prior to this, the price of capital21 and the price of labor will determine the proportions in which these factors will be used (expressed by iso-cost lines).

Table 1. Sizes of different ships, building prices, operation cost and total cost per dwt, 2005.

Source: author; data selected from Stopford (2009: p. 224).

Graph 4. Long run equilibrium of a shipping company having 2 scales. Source: author.

In order to establish a shipping firm, we need to build, or buy, 1 at least, vessel, and, as shown, let this be of a size of 50,000 dwt initially. To do this, one needs OA units of Labor and OB units of Capital, given the technology prevailing in the shipbuilding industry at the time of her order. Isoquants show what the shipping firm wishes to do, given its production function. The iso-cost lines22 tell us what a shipping company can do, by having the funds to buy the vessels, hire the crew etc. Using 2nd hand vessels, one introduces no new technical progress. But 2nd hand ships cannot be excluded from this investigation because they change the capital of a shipping company.

We also need 2 years, on average, for vessel’s construction, depending on the phase of the shipping cycle. We also need an amount of $, say $30 m - $60 m, and $1.5m p.a. for the labor cost, shown by the iso-cost lines. An iso-cost line shows the fixed amount of money, which can pay the company to get the combination of 2 inputs. For the 2nd hand vessel, the time to obtain her may be 1 - 3 months, due to the existence of a well-organized 2nd hand market, as mentioned!

The right-angle lines are known as “isoquants” or “equal product curves” or “curves bringing equal quantity of product”. These indicate a complementary relationship between Ct and Lt. This means that the combination of Ct and Lt, shown by them, provides a single production of 95% of 50,000 dwt or 150,000 dwt23.

If a shipowner wants to achieve a higher production than 50,000 dwt, then another isoquant appears. In this second case, we have a higher size of the ship (3 times larger) and an increased amount of capital (OD) and a lower amount of labor (OC). The iso-cost line may be:

S = OD × $ 600 + OC × $ 75000 . (7)

There may be a low limit, we believe, of the quantity of labor, which is necessary24, and thus we may say that labor, Lt ≥ 18 persons, given the state of technology. The size of crew is determined by law, and it takes certain technological advances into account (e.g., an automatic engine room).

7.1. The Optimal Freight Rates during a Shipping Cycle

Assume that we have one plant (one ship), which has a fixed capacity (in dwt). Let K (*) be the maximum number of ton-miles that she can produce per period of time (=one voyage). The company runs also a fixed cost F, which varies over the units of production (average fixed cost). The marginal cost is constant at 0c (Graph 5). The equilibrium production is at K (*) (which is also optimal providing the largest $ value of the possible benefits in excess of costs (Train, 1991: p. 13). We drew also a MC curve, the s, the way we believe to be more correct.

We assume that the demand is higher at the upper phase of the shipping cycle (boom), Dp, and lower at the downward phase (depression), Do. The period for each demand is not equal, but the peak is 3/8 of the whole period and the off-peak is 5/8, over a cycle of 8 years (Stopford, 2009). As shown the freight rate

Graph 5. Two Marginal cost curves with a fixed capacity K. Source: inspired from those in Train (1991: p. 242).

Fr is equal to oc (=MC). The demand is satisfied by the existing ship capacity. However, OQ1 < than K (*) and so firm loses money. This is the result of a depression and of a low-capacity utilization. Interesting is that Cobb-Douglas (1928: p. 152) distinguished production according to times of prosperity and depressions.

The way we drew the MC curve, s, assumes that MC is falling as capacity utilization increases towards 100%. This MC curve permits for a ship to undertake a voyage at say 60% of her dwt, given Fr. We assume, however, that the company at OQ1 < 60%K (*) will refuse to undertake the unprofitable production (voyage).

When demand is Dp, capacity cannot cover demand, and so freight rate may be raised by demand and supply. The ship earns revenues in excess of her variable cost (not shown). Given that the 2 periods, we defined them unequal, the excess revenue will be lower than the loss in non-peak phase. To break-even we have to bring-in fixed cost as well. During low demand the capacity is wasted and the ship may be removed from the market (laid-up), and in the long run replaced by a smaller vessel. The reverse is also true.

7.2. Reality Differs from Theory!

Worth noting is that a shipping firm, despite theory, can change in practice its fixed capital, if its management wishes, in short time (Graph 6). This means that either shipping short run is very short or a shipping company is always in the long run!

What, however, we could not find in modern maritime economic textbooks, is a short run (Graph 7) equilibrium of a shipping firm! Suppose a shipping firm owns 1 ship (1 plant), producing OQ1 ton miles at a freight rate OP1, during 1 voyage, at full capacity utilization.

As shown, the vessel is chartered for 1 voyage of OQ1 thousand-ton miles at a freight rate OP1, at full capacity utilization, 100%. When the vessel is full, no further “production” is possible, and SR(AC) is at a minimum and vertical, and SR(MC) curve is vertical too as well AVC. The Marginal, and Average total costs and variable ones, are falling as cargo loaded increases till vessel is full. The cost per ton-mile (ship’s another average cost in operations) also falls as vessel loads-up to her load line, and distance increases.

If the capacity utilization is not full, or over a certain %, the vessel will have losses, and she will not undertake the charter, we believe, as mentioned. If LR(AC) (Graph 9) < SR(AC), it will pay the firm to buy/build a larger vessel! Shipping is an industry of increasing returns to scale, or decreasing costs, (assuming fixed factor prices of labor and capital according to theory). According to Varian (1990: p. 351) the short run average cost curves must be tangent to the long run average cost curve. It is apparent that LRAC < SRAC.

The short run equilibrium of the (shipping) industry is rather an easy task (Stopford, 2009: p. 165) (Graph 8).

Graph 6. How reality is different from theory? Source: author.

Graph 7. A shipping company in equilibrium in the short run producing OQ1 per 1 voyage at freight rater OP1. Source: author.

Graph 8. Short-run equilibrium of shipping industry. Source: author.

As shown, in the short run, the supply of ships becomes vertical at Q*, which is the maximum world fleet size, together with a maximum demand for ton miles D1 (ships × distances, given speed and port time). Any additions to fleet needs time, of about 2 years on average, depending on the phase of the shipping cycle. If demand for ships increases, (in the short run), from D3 to D1, this will result to increases in freight rates, OF3 to OF1 (Graph 8). This is the short run equilibrium of the shipping industry.

We may follow now economic theory again and apply it to maritime microeconomics, presenting the short-run and the long run average cost Curves together (Graph 9). The company’s fleet comes in 3 different sizes: small, medium and large. Once the shipping firm commits itself to a production facility of a particular size, it can change output only by varying the quantity of inputs other than ship’s size/number of ships (capital) in the short run. For each ship size we drew an associated short run average cost function (SRAC).

We have two options: 1) to connect the tangent points of each shipping SRACs curves, Q1-3, with the LRAC curve, and draw the shipping long run average cost. 2) To connect the low points of SRAC Q1-3, and draw the LRAC curve. The LRAC cost is falling as the size of production increases by increasing all inputs due to scale economies. Microeconomists argue that it is better-off to produce at the tangency point, where the per unit costs are lower par excellence, due to scale economies, (shown by the red arrow as there is the optimum scale of the ship!

Stopford (2009: p. 166) dealt with shipping long run cost curves drawing the supply and demand in long-term adjustments, between 1980 and 1992.

The freight rate is determined in the long-run by the Supply of ship space and the demand for it, given distances and average speed (Graph 10). The supply and demand are the King and the Queen in maritime markets, which together determine the freight rate (the price of shipping services). Graph 10 is self-understood.

8. Part IV: The Real Scale Economies in Maritime Industry

The history of shipping economics provides valuable lessons, though history may be not repeated, as many say (Goulielmos, 2009)! The low freight rates (prices of shipping services) prohibit the building of ships. Prices (freight rates) must allow the owner to recoup his/her capital and the shipbuilder to make a profit. So, technical progress depends on the level of freight rates expected to be obtained by the newly-built ships.

Graph 9. Short run equilibrium of a shipping company in 3 scales. Source: author.

Graph 10. Equilibrium of shipping industry and of the firm in the long-run. Source: author.

Ships are destined to serve the world seaborne trade (demand). The seaborne trade under normal circumstances increases, as shown (Figure 1).

As shown, the seaborne trade increased 1.5 times since 1982, in 23 years. This is the proxy demand for ships, and its volume is expressed in billion tons. Important is to take into account the distances involved, and the time spent in ports and crossing canals, to estimate correctly the seaborne demand. If we take as a yardstick a ship of a handy size of 25,000 dwt, she increased in size 2 times from 25,000 dwt in 1970 to 35,000 in 1985 and 50,000 in 2007! This is due to the increased parcel size to begin with.

Graph 11 shows the 5 main factors which determine the size of a vessel and thus maritime scale economies.

Though ports care for providing suitable water depths for vessels of an increasing draft, they may delay this process, which is very expensive and perhaps repeated25. The distances are a factor that needs much attention. They may increase, meaning higher demand for the same trade, but they can diminish, if new supplies crop up in more near places vis-à-vis consumption centers. Certain times, suppliers of a higher quality of a raw material have emerged (e.g., iron ore from Australia to Japan vis-à-vis from Brazil).

Sometimes canals were closed making distances… longer. Demand may be excessive also if ships are stuck in ports waiting for loading or unloading (congestion). Certain costs run by the vessel, are size related, like most port expenses. If vessel’s distance is short and the vessel is large, then port expenses are a heavier burden per year. So, larger vessels seek for longer distances and fewer port calls.

Important is also the parcel size, meaning the unit load, which differs from cargo to cargo, and is determined by the maximum size of each order placed by the importers at one time. This is influenced by the phase of the shipping cycle

Figure 1. Seaborne Trade, 1982-2005. Source: data from Stopford, 2009: p. 719.

Graph 11. 5 Main factors determining the size of a vessel and ES. Source: author.

and the maximum storage capacity of the importers, the time they need to transform the unit load of raw material into ready products. The parcel size also depends on the size of importers as the larger ones will import larger quantities every time and reap economies of scale. Oil, iron ore, grain, coal, fertilizers, etc. and especially all dry cargoes and liquid cargoes are transported in large quantities in bulk (unpacked).

The average bulk carrier increased further in size between 1981 and 2006 from 34,000 dwt to 58,000 or 1.7 times (Figure 2).

Future scale economies are indicated by ships on order. Figure 3 shows this trend, where the bulk carrier size started from 64,214 dwt in Dec. 2000 and reached the 81,284 in Dec. 2011, or 1.27 times larger, and since 1981 2.4 times larger. Economies of scale reduced since 2009 due to global financial crisis in end 2008! In dwt terms Figure 4 shows ships on order (tons) since 2000 till 2011 and Figure 5 shows the number of ships on order between 2000 and 2011.

Figure 2. Average bulk carrier size trend, 1981-2006. Source: author; data from Stopford (2009: p. 76).

Figure 3. Bulk carrier fleet on order, 2000-2011: average size. Source: Author; data from Branch & Robarts (2014: p. 57).

Figure 4. Size of Tonnage of the bulk carriers on order, 2000-2011. Source: as in previous Figure 3.

Figure 5. Number of bulk carriers on order, 2000-2011. Source: as in previous Figure 3.

As shown, tonnage and ships on order are influenced by the end-2008 shipping depression, and this affected adversely also the ships’ average size and scale economies! Moreover, the number of ships on order, which are the agents of embodied technical progress, fell from a high of 3347 ships on order in 2008 (end) to 2,268 in Dec. 2011 (~32% less)!

Worth noting is that the costs of operation, for voyage and for capital, do not follow the size of the ship! Table 1 below summarizes certain facts related to the size of vessels.

As shown, scale economies are derived first from building price. A vessel almost 6 times larger, has a building cost per dwt 2.5 times lower than the 30,000 dwt one. Secondly, operating cost per dwt fell from $40 to $11.8. The total cost per dwt (long run average cost) fell from $191 to $74 going from 30,000 to 170,000 dwt. Given that we talk about new-buildings, we are in the long run. As the size of the vessel increased almost 6 times, the average total cost in the long run fell from $191 to $74 (2.6 times less) (=ES).

Bunker costs, and operation costs, however, increase by size in absolute terms, no doubt: a vessel of 30,000 dwt consumes 22t/day and pays $1.54m26 p.a., against 39t/day of the 170,000 dwt one and $2.73m/year. The hire is $8.53m/year for the larger one against 4.02m for the smaller one. The smaller vessel (30,000 dwt) had almost 3 times higher cost per dwt p.a. (average cost) ($185 per dwt/year against $66/dwt/year for the 170,000 dwt).

Table 2 indicates the status quo of the trend of large ships in tankers and dry cargoes trades in 2007.

Table 2. The market share of the standardized sizes of vessels, tankers and dry cargoes, worldwide in 2007.

Source: data from Stopford (2009).

As shown, the larger vessels in each category get the lion’s share in seaborne trade transportation! The important precondition for this, however, is to maintain scale economies in maritime markets meaning to create the appropriate parcel sizes. This in turn means, when building new ships, to avoid the coming depressions!

9. Part V: Scale Economies through Tanker Chartering

The history of the “tanker freight rates” is interesting (Buckley, 2008: p. 165-170), “Intertanko” (1988). In 1969, the brokers in London and NY introduced the “Worldwide Tanker Nominal rate scale”, known as “Worldscale” (in 1969). We will use this index in its new form to show the scale economies in tankers in real business life. The index in force will be used, which is applied in 1989 (01/01). This index is based on metric tons (1000 kgs) instead of long tons (1016 kgs) of the previous one.

Table 3 summarizes the impact of size on ship’s cost.

As shown, the size of a tanker (75,000 dwt) performed a round trip from port A to port B and back, and had a cost of $13.08 per metric ton of oil carried (average cost). The annual cost made up by: port expenses $90,000 (9.6%), the cost of bunkers of $282,800 (30.15%) and the rest of all other costs of $565,200 (60.25%) (=$938,000 total).

Now, we increase the size of the above tanker to 225,000 dwt, or 3 times exactly, and her speed by 1 knot. This will shorten the time at sea by 2.78 days, but the time in ports it will increase it by 4 additional days. The fuel consumption will increase27 from 2800 tons to 5271! Moreover, Water = 100 t more; stores = 100 tons more; and by adding fuel, we have a dwt of 219,029 tons less (=production). This is a better % of space utilization of 97.346 for the larger ship and only 95.6%

Table 3. Long-run average total cost for a tanker of 75,000 dwt and 225,000, 2008.

Notes: 1) Port costs are $15,000 in port A and $75,000 in port B = $90,000. 2) 96 hours laytime plus 12 hours; Panama Canal transit 24 hours; Suez Canal transit 30 hours. Source: data from Buckley (2008), p. 165-170.

for the smaller, meaning an additional income of 1.65%. The port costs increased to $360,000 from $90,000 (4 times)! So, the total costs of the larger ship amounted to $1,472,211 consisting of: fuel $532,371 (36.15%); 360,000 (24.45%) for port expenses and $579,840 (39.4%) for all other costs.

Per dwt this last cost gives $6.72, against $13.08, or 51.4% less long run average cost. Economies of scale exist, as the size of the vessel increased 3 times, the long run average cost, fell by half (51.4%)!

The port cost, by the way, indicates that the size of the vessel is punished by the 4 times higher port cost, because port costs are based on ship’s GRT or NRT (alternative measures of size used by ports) and rarely on dwt! This is not fair and the larger vessel should pay maximum $270,000 port expenses, we reckon (according to her increased size in dwt). This is why, elsewhere, we argued that ports obstruct the scale economies in ships! This means that ports have to revise their price policy to welcome more larger ships.

Historically, ports based their price policy on the assumption that ships with larger capacity (GRT, NRT, dwt) obtain higher income, and so they have to pay a higher amount to ports, as ports were considered “partners”! If so, should ships in ballast pay a symbolic low amount as they carry no cargo?

10. Conclusion

We showed, mathematically, the scale economies in Shipping industry by using the Cobb-Douglas production function and assuming: A = 1, α + b > 1, α = 1 and b = 0.03, a double quantity of capital (twice a smaller vessel) and 10% less quantity of labor (crew; from 20 to 18 persons). We achieved almost 2 times additional production (in dwt) (+1.99).

Then we assumed a rise in vessels speed by 1 knot or from 14 to 15, meaning A = 1.07. So, the future production Qt + 1 increased also by 1.07 × Qt. This assumption of 7% additional technical embodied progress remains to be proved by an econometric model, but in another paper. Finally, production increased by 2.13 times indicating increasing returns to scale.

Marshall inherited to economists 2 economic periods among 4 called short and long. We showed that shipping companies can be most of their life in the long run, if they so wish. This implied specific strategies during short run for the company to stay alive, despite what Keynes said that in the long run everybody is dead. The truth is that one has to stay alive in the short run to be round in the long run!

We tried also to fill-in certain deficiencies in the maritime microeconomic theory, like: the equilibrium of the plant (the vessel); the short run and long run equilibria of a shipping company; the equilibrium of shipping industry and the equilibrium during a depression or during a boom. In most of these endeavors, we used right-angled isoquant curves.

Maritime scale economies proved to exist using data found in Stopford (2009) and tanker chartering (new “Worldscale”). A tanker, which increased by 3 times her size and obtained 1 knot higher speed, reduced the long run average total cost by half!

We also reached three important conclusions: 1) ports “sabotage” scale economies in ships by charging them excessively, where the size of the vessel trebled, the port cost increased 4 times. 2) Depressions cause scale economies in ships to be postponed. 3) Scale economies can be increased provided that parcel size also increases (the demand for larger ships has to be there to reap scale economies). In fact, with this third conclusion, we brought “coal to Newcastle”, and “owls to Athens”, as the same argued by Adam Smith in 1776, saying: that the “extent of the market determines the division of labor” (Besanko et al., 2013: pp. 70-71).

NOTES

1Savings which come from the increase in the variety (range) of goods, and/or services produced, unknown before 1990s.

2Covering a number of sea miles of 1855.2 meters length.

3Ports, Canals, Sea (weather, waves, winds, currents, depths, swells, tides etc.), bunker suppliers, tug owners, agents, charterers, suppliers, clubs/insurance companies, crew, marine accidents, ship-repairs, dry dockers, pirates, terrorists, thieves, crew unions, coastal police (PSC), port authorities, pollution and safety guards, etc. all play a role in shipping production!

4Though excluded by economists in a “two-variables” environment!

5Meaning the time when a ship moves without being paid.

6Suez Canal is famous for its impact on shipping in its 1956 short and 1967 long closures, and in 2021, with the giant containership (“Ever Given”), which blocked the canal’s passage!

7This means a number of changes like: proper sea depth, suitable length of quays, right loading/unloading equipment, computerization of things (!) for the least port time, etc.

8Oil and dry cargoes are of low value per ton, but in large quantities may arrive at serious $m amounts.

9The long-run average cost curve envelops the short-run average cost curves. Called also a planning curve showing the least cost of producing a given level of output.

10To allocate labor to the activity in which it produces most. A best use of skills. Labor is divided among tasks according to its comparative advantage. No one person carries-out all tasks. Known as specialization.

11This reminded me of the differential rent obtained by the more fertile land at the time of Ricardo. In his theory, the price of an agricultural product is determined by the cost of the less fertile land, called “marginal land”, which is brought into cultivation to satisfy demand. The more fertile land has a lower cost and so there will be a difference (a rent) vis-à-vis price. Thus, ships with higher cost required to satisfy demand will obtain a freight rate covering their average variable cost at least, which will be higher than that of the more efficient ships, which will get an extra revenue (a rent). Efficient ships are not necessarily the youngest ships (Goulielmos, 2021a), as mentioned.

12This means that charterers believe that the services of ships they are going to use are identical. This means that ship’s age, her owner, maintenance, safety, security, etc. do not differentiate the nature of the service. In other words, there is one condition of perfect competition. The last decades, however, especially in tankers, charterers prefer ships under 15 years of age because they fear to have a marine accident. This has distorted perfect competition in shipping economics.

13They characteristically wrote: “the bigger, the better”.

14From the beginning, we put emphasis on the prices of services produced, because by examining the side of a maximum production first, and then of a lower long run average cost, we may assume that the prices of services always permit expansion to a higher scale!

15By 1990s we had à economies of: growth, learning and scale; after 1990s we had à economies of scope, and of density.

16It can be shown that an optimal production is a function of the price of the product, i.e., wages and the price of capital (Chiang & Wainwright, 2005: p. 337-338).

17Qt = A × 21 × 0.900.03 = A × 2 × 0.9968441 = 1.9936883 and A = 1.07, Qt = 2.133246481, going from 14 knots to 15 knots.

18Neoclassical economists, and Solow, are fond of α + b = 1. This is so because then Euler’s theorem holds determining the “distribution of income” mathematically and not politically! The value of production is shared by Ct and Lt in accordance with their value of marginal products, which somebody may consider fair.

19Marshall avoided to define short run in calendar time and what he meant was “operational” time.

20Marshall wrote about “time periods”, but he considered them as no inventions of Nature. He wrote: “Nature has drawn no such lines in the economic conditions of actual life” (p. 314). And these periods were not wanted! The time of adaptation to changing circumstances of producers and of consumers (Blaug, 1997: p. 354), Marshall meant by time periods.

21Primarily determined by the price of steel for ship building.

22 S = a P C t + b P L t (6), where PCt is the price of one unit of capital and PLt is the price of 1 crew member on average, and a and b are the quantities of Ct and Lt used in production. (6) is the so-called budget line.

23The dwt production is 5% less in the form of cargo carried, due to the weight that other inputs have (water, stores, bunkers etc.).

24This is an assumption at the present state of shipbuilding technology. Research for ships with zero crew is going-on. Automation is the technical progress that has reduced labor on board, so far. Labor on board is reduced due to its cost, but also due to its difficult availability in numbers and quality required. In shipping, technical progress is subject to safety of the ship and of cargo and crew. Given, however, that new capital cost covers the 50% of total annual cost, labor cost is only 15% of total operating cost out of say $10m p.a.

25Ports where rivers may flow into them, bringing materials, they have to dig sea bottom frequently.

26At $200/ton. The vessel is 5.7 times larger and consumes 1.8 times more bunkers than the 30,000 dwt.

27Fuel at sea 2218 t × 2; reserve 555 t; 200 t for other purpose; 80 t for ports. Price $101/ton = $532,371.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflicts of interest regarding the publication of this paper.

References

[1] Besanko, D., Dranove, D., Shanley, M., & Schaefer, S. (2013). Economics of Strategy (6th ed.). John Wiley & Sons.
[2] Bilas, R. A. (1967). Microeconomic Theory: A Graphical Analysis. McGraw Hill Co.
[3] Blaug, M. (1997). Economic Theory in Retrospect (5th ed.). Cambridge University Press.
https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511805639
[4] Branch, A. E., & Robarts, M. (2014). Branch’s Elements of Shipping (9th ed.). Routledge.
https://doi.org/10.4324/9781315767154
[5] Buckley, J. J. (2008). The Business of Shipping (8th ed.). Cornell Maritime Press.
[6] Chiang, A. C., & Wainwright, K. (2005). Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics (4th ed.). McGraw Hill.
[7] Cobb, C. W., & Douglas, P. H. (1928). A Theory of Production. American Economic Review, 18, 139-165.
[8] Douglas, P. H. (1948). Are There Laws of Production? American Economic Review, 38, 1-41.
[9] Eltis, W. A. (1966). Economic Growth: Analysis and Policy. Hutchinson University Library.
[10] Goulielmos, A. M. (2009). Is History Repeated? Cycles and Recessions in Shipping Markets, 1929 and 2008. Shipping & Transport Logistics, 1, 329-360.
https://doi.org/10.1504/IJSTL.2009.027679
[11] Goulielmos, A. M. (2018b). Time and Equilibrium: 2 Important, but Invisible, Concepts of Economics, with Application to Shipping Industry. Modern Economy, 9, 536-561.
https://doi.org/10.4236/me.2018.93035
[12] Goulielmos, A. M. (2018c). Psychological Economics: The Case-Studies of Eurozone, Global Economic Crisis and Greece. Modern Economy, 5, 1792-1820.
https://doi.org/10.4236/me.2018.911113
[13] Goulielmos, A. M. (2021a). A Microeconomic (Vintage) Model of a Shipping Company: A Proposed Depreciation Strategy. Modern Economy, 720, 27-48.
[14] Goulielmos, A. M. (2021b). How a Country Can Reach the Top World Shipping Positions by Creating Leading Companies? The Late John Angelicoussis Case Study. Modern Economy, 12, 1004-1034.
https://doi.org/10.4236/me.2021.125052
[15] Goulielmos, A. M. (2018a). Self-Reinforcing Mechanisms in Economics: With Two Case-Studies from Shipping Industry. Modern Economy, 9, 1313-1337.
https://doi.org/10.4236/me.2018.97085
[16] Intertanko (1988). The New Worldscale—A New Chartering Tool (p. 53). International Association of Independent Tanker Owners (INTERTANKO).
[17] Lorange, P. (2009). Shipping Strategy: Innovating for Success. Cambridge University Press.
[18] Marshall, A. (1890). Principles of Economics: An Introductory Volume (1st ed.). Macmillan & Co Ltd.
[19] Marshall, A. (1920). Principles of Economics: An Introductory Volume (8th ed., 1961 Reprint.). Macmillan & Co Ltd.
[20] Pearce, D. W. (General Editor). (1992). Macmillan Dictionary of Modern Economics (4th ed.). Palgrave.
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-22136-3
[21] Priesmeyer, H. R. (1992). Organizations and Chaos: Defining the Methods of Nonlinear Management. Quorum Books.
[22] Robinson, J. (1965). The Accumulation of Capital (2nd ed.). Macmillan.
[23] Stopford, M. (2009). Maritime Economics (3rd ed.). Routledge.
https://doi.org/10.4324/9780203891742
[24] Tarski, I. (1979). Economy of Scale in Transportation. International Journal of Transport Economics, 6, 21-39.
[25] Train, K. E. (1991). Optimal Regulation: The Economic Theory of Natural Monopoly. The MIT Press.
[26] Varian, H. R. (1990). Intermediate Microeconomics: A Modern Approach (2nd ed.). W.W Norton & Co.
[27] Viner, J. (1931). Cost Curves and Supply Curves. Review of National Economy, 3, 23-46. (In German). Reprinted in Stigler-Boulding (Ed.), Readings in Price Theory (pp. 23-46). Springer.

Copyright © 2024 by authors and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

Creative Commons License

This work and the related PDF file are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.